BRIEF GUIDE TO THE ECONOMIES OF THE SOVIET BLOC

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4
Release Decision: 
RIFPUB
Original Classification: 
S
Document Page Count: 
65
Document Creation Date: 
November 9, 2016
Document Release Date: 
January 8, 1999
Sequence Number: 
3
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
November 5, 1954
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4.pdf3.5 MB
Body: 
Approved For Release 1999/0902 : CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003,4~ _F PROVISIONAL INTELLIGENCE REPORT BRIEF GUIDE TO THE ECONOMIES OF THE SOVIET BLOC CIA/RR PR-74 5 November 1954 .. . MEtV1't~C~. ~- crc~.~s~ t~C~ r~ ` ? IN C! P.SS. CJ PaJ r H t ? ~ .,`? .- ~. CENTRAL INTELLIGENCE AGENCY OFFICE OF RESEARCH AND REPORTS Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060 3-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CfA-RDP79-01093A00060006p003-4 WARNING This material contains information .affecting the National Defense of the United States within'. the meaning of the espionage laws, Title 18, USC, Secs. 793 and 794, the trans- mission or revelation of which in any manner to an unauthorized person is prohibited by law. Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 PROVISIONAL INTELLIGENCE REPORT ~r BRIEF GUIDE TO TfiE ECONOMIES OF THE SOVIET BLOC CIA/RR PR-74 (ORR Project 13.344) NOTICE The data and conclusi-ons contained in this report do not .necessarily represent the final position of ORR and should be regarded as provisional only and subject to revision. Comments and data which may be available to the user ase solicited. CENTRAL INTELLIGENCE AGENCY Office of Research and Reports ~~~ ~:~~, Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E -C -R -E -T FOREWORD This report is designed for the reader who has a very general interest in the facts of Soviet economic life. It contains the necessary minimum of background information on the history, organi- zation,-and goals of the economic systems of the countries concerned and also the most recent data pertaining to the actual operation of these--economies in the aggregate and in some detail. Thus it is hoped that this handbook will enable the reader to view the current economic pursuits of the peoples in the Soviet sphere with some historic perspective and some .appreciation of their dynamism. S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T CONTENTS. Page I. Description 1 A . USSR . 1 B. European Satellites 12 C . Communist Ck~.tna 13 II. Recent Developments in the Bloc Economies 16 B. European .Satellites .- 20 C . Communist China 21 III. National Accounts . . 22 A. Gross National Product. . 22 B. Gross National Product by Use . ? 24 C. Gross National Product by Industry of Origin. 25 IV. Economic and Industrial Base. 26 A. Population and Manpower 27 1. USSR . . 2'~ 2. European Satellites 31 3. Communist China . 3~ B. Agriculture 34 1. USSR . 34 2. European Satellites 37 3. Communist China 39 C . Industry. 41 1. Energy. 41 2 . Metals . ~ 46 3. Building Materials. 48 4. Chemicals 48 5. Manufacturing 50 6. Military End Items. 51 S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E -C -R -E -T D . Transportation 51 1. USSR . 51 2. European Satellites. 54 3. Communist China. 55 E. Services ... 56 F. Foreign Trade. . 57 1. Gross Natiional Product of the Soviet Bloc and NATO Powers by Principal Areas, 1938-53 . 3. Division of Gross National Product by End Use~USSR, Selected Years, 1838-53; US, 1953 . Gross National Product by Industry of Origin~USSR, Selected Years, 1938-53~ US, 1953. . 26 ~+. Population and Employment in the USSR as of 1 January 1939, 1947, 1950, and 1953. . . 5? Population and Employment in the European Satellites, 1 January 1947 and 1953 ? 32 6. Production of Major Crops in Communist China, 1949-52. 40 7. Production of Selected Commodities in the Soviet Bloc. 42 8. Freight Transportation in the USSR by Major Carrier Type 1950 to Mid-156. .. 53 S-E~-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 ": CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 cIA/~t ~ _7~ (ORR Project 13.3~~+) I. Description. A. Ufl~R . S-E-C-R-E-T ~L22EF GUIDE TO TAE ECONOMIES t?F TAS SOY.~T B.LOC* 1. Soviet Economic Policy. a,. Role of the. State. Economic decision-making in the USSR is almost ex- clusively a function of central political bodies rather than a market mechanism. The concrete economic policies. laid down. by the central authority to channel economic activity toward the attainment of long- range goals are thus implemented directly by the state planning organs. In this way the attainment of the state's goals is not left. to the market place, where consumer sovereignty could dictate a pace of industrial development and military expansion quite at variance with the wishes of the central authority. A wide gap between the interests of the population and the government, induced by the policy of a high rate of invest- ment and a low rate of consumption, has necessitated the extension of centralized control over an ever-increasing number of commodities and activities. Control over agricultural production was relaxed somewhat during World War II, to provide greater personal incentives,. but was resumed almost i.mYaediately thereafter. In 1952, about 1,600 commodities were subject to strict priority allocation by the central authority to avoid the possibility of their being diverted into uses of lesser importance in terms of the state's economic goals. The basic commitment of the Soviet economy to rapid military and industrial growth has necessitated the direction of a ~ The estimates and conclusions contained in this report repre-sent the best judgment of the responsible analyst as of 16 August 195+? S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02: C1A-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T large portion of the country's resources into investment in the pro- ducer goods industries. This direction has been accomplished by economic policies designed to depress consumption and thereby free resources. for other uses. For example, pricing p.alicy is designed to. ration scarce consumer goods by means of a huge tax component in their price, while the absence- of a tax in the prices of producer goads provides the state with relatively cheap supplies of industrial materials.. .And collectivization in agriculture., by making deliveries of produce to the state obligatory at prices which are probably lase than the cost of production, has had the same effect of depressing the real income of the rural population. Soviet economic policy has aimed at achieving a maximum redistribution of the labor Porce in favor of the urban industrialized areas with a minimtum expansion of investment, es- pecially in urban housing. Housing construction as a percentage of total investment in the USSR in the pr-ewer period from. 192$ to 1937 was only about 9 percent annually in contrast to the US, where housing has ranged i'rom 15 to 25 percent of total investment annually since 1880. In 1939, only about ~+3 square feet of living space per person was available in Soviet urban areas. This condition was the result of the low level of housing investment accc~panied by a net movement of 25 million persona frown rural to urban areas in the period 1926-39. During the postwar period, Soviet investment. in housing increased to a level of 15 to 18 percent. of total imrestment. Although a substantial portion of this increase can be attributed to reconstruction of war-damaged housing, its continuation since 19+8 may indicate a more lasting change in policy. c. Growth of Industrial Production.. The Soviet policy of allocating investment- in favor of industrial rather than non.-industrial sectors and in favor of pro- ducer goods over consumer goods within the industrial sector has achieved a very rapid change in the volume and c~positian of i.n- dustriel output. This industrial revolution was accoanpanied by a general inflationary trend in prices beginning shortly after the launching of the First Five. Year Flan in 1928. Increases in indus- trial wages tended to outstrip increases in labor productivity, and the demand for agricultural raw materials caused extreme pressure an .agricultural prices. Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Rising prices in industry were met initially by a policy of extensive industrial. subsidies. This. policy continued un- til 1936, when the first in a series. of subsidy reductions was made, accompanied by substantial upward revisions in the prices. of indus- trial products. After the major reorganization of wholesale indus- tfii$1 prices in 19+9, the use of subsidies in Soviet, industry was .partially discontinued although high-coat operations such as the timber industry and certain favored activities continued to receive them. These pricing problems and other technical considera- tions make it difficult to measure realistically the actual increases in industrial production since 1928. It is probable, however, that the average annual rate of growth in Soviet industrial production throughout the First and Second Five Year Flans (1928-37) was in the neighborhood of 15 pe.rce~. In the period of the Third Five Year Plan (1938-~+2), several factors can be isolated which contributed to the substantial drop in the average annual rate of growth of indus- trial production to a level of approximately 5 percent--growth of the industrial labor force was less rapid because of inductions iota the armed forces; a diversion of resources into military production from investment by its nature caused a decline in the rate of growth. Industrial production during the war years declined absolutely as a result of the German. invasion. The level of indus- trial output in 19+6 was only slightly above that of 1935? The high average rate of growth of industrial production during the Fourth Five Year Plan (about 20 percent annually) was the result in large part of postwar reconstruction. Over-all measures of Soviet industrial growth present an incomplete picture of the economy. Productivity growth has varied widely from one industry to another. The rate of growth of labor productivity in the basic heavy industries such as steel, metals and machinery manufactures has been far above the average for industry as a whole. C onsumer goods industries have lagged far behind the average, as would be expected in light of Soviet invest- ment policy, given the usual high degree of correlation between labor productivity and investment growth. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T d, Problems of Inventories. The forced rate of industrialization in the USER has created a number of problems of disproportionate development. Indus- trial plant development, for example, has leaned fore toward self- contained factories independent of a network of parts suppliers in order to minimize inventory and. transportation requirements. Where, however, planned inventory or transportation facilities were actually inadequate, delays and bottlenecks inevitably developed. This situa- tion could have been altered only through larger allocations of in- vestment to the transportation system and to the building up of more adequate inventories of component parts and raw materials. The Soviet planners have elected instead an. economic course of action highly tempered with military considerations--the building up of centrally owned stocks of reserve materials subject to greater control over their release into production cYtannels than would be the case if such materials were dispersed throughout the industrial machine in the form of larger inventories at the lisp-osal of individual plants. The extensive Soviet stockpiling program has created a highly liquid military asset which at the same time is available for release to industry to break major bottlenecks in supply . e. Problems of Agriculture.. The basic commitment of the central authority tc a rapid rate of industrialization has considerably influenced Soviet agricultural policy. IQot only has it limited significantly the magnitude of imrestment allocated to the agricultural sector, but the direction of that investment has been aJ.med toward labor-saving forms (machinery and equipment) rather than the more labor-intensive forms such as fertilizers.. This policy of emphasizing mechanization, which was made possible through the collectivization program (which greatly increased the average size of farms) freed large numbers of rural-workers for urbanization. After the connpletion of postwar reconstruction in 19+8, when industrial production generally had reached the prewar level, some shift in investment policy in favor of agriculture took place. The proportion of total investment allocated to industry declined steadily from a 19~+E-~+8 average of 63 percent of budgetary expenditure to about ~+5 percent in 1952. Agriculture gained a Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 substantial portion 4f this diverted budgetary expenditure in connec- tion with large-scale plans of afforestation and irrigation. Prior to 19+8, significant expansion of agriculture to sub marginal land was prevented by the reluctance of the central authority to provide the large amounts of capital in the form of irrigation shelter-belts, transportation facilities, fertilizers,. and bybrid seed necessary to the expansion of the sown area. The stringent Soviet agricultural investment policy has denied to this sector the possibility of altering the relative proportions of grain and fodder crops to allow for increased live- stock production. The necessity for feeding the population even at the low level of consumption in the USSR precluded, during the pre- war years, the- more lavish use of resources required in the produc- tion of livestock. Further, in prewar years, the predominant share of livestock was owned privately by the members of ko7_khozes (collective farms.), who were limited in their holdings both by statute and by their ability to obtain feed. The development of livestock breeding was thus actua]_ly retarded by Soviet agricultural policy. Thee number of livestock, which had been greatly reduced during the early period of collectivization, did not regain the pre- collectivization level until the last prewar years. In. the postwar years, especially after 19+8, agricultural policy has emphasized livestock breeding on the collective farms as opposed to private livestock breeding by members of the kolkhozes, a policy which re- quired the allocation of a large amount of investment in building animal shelters and fodder storage space. Relative prices of meat and feed grains, however, have been such as to make livestock pro- duction unprofitable. The amalgamation of smaller collectives into larger ones which began in 1950, is partially in response to the needs of the livestock program, although statements of Soviet officials explain the policy of further amalgamation of collectives in terms of the achievement of a more rational foundation for com- plex, all-round kolkhoz development as opposed to one-sided pro- duction. The extent of the amalgamation which was begun in 1950 is evidenced by the decrease in the number of kolkhozes from 252,000 in 1950 to 97.,000 by October 1952.. f. Problems of Geography. Much of Soviet economic policy has been influenced by the disadvantages associated with the immense size of the Soviet land area and the unfavorable distribution of economic resources within that area. The policy of regional self-sufficiency in the S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T postwar period has undoubtedly been to some degree a response to this problem, although the influence of strategic military considerations is obviously great also. The high proportion of productive effort which must be expended in the USSR to overcome space barriers has caused the central authority to lay great stress on minimizing the transport component of total costs. About 30 percent of total coal production is consumed by the transportation effort. Postwar economic policy has concentrated on the reduction of this transportation burden by developing local sources of energy and by reducing .regional interdependence. The maldistribution of high-quality energy re- sources, however, has hindered the implementation of this policy. Soviet industrialization had increased the average length of haul of coal from x+85 :kilometers in 1913 to 695 kilometers in 19+6. The 1950 plan goal called for a reduction to 650 kilometers. 2. The Organization and Control of Economic Activity in the USSR. a. The Communist Party. At the apex of the economic administration of the USSR is the Presidium (formerly the Politburo) of the Communist Party. To carry out its decisions,. the Presidium utilizes the machinery of the Soviet state. On the basis of the Party Presidium:!s policy decisions, designed to meet what are regarded as the crucial internal and ex- ternal problems which confront the nation,. general directives are issued to the State Planning Commission (Gosplan), a staff attached to the Council of Ministers. Gosplan with the assistance of other agencies translates these directives into Five Year Plans and sub- sidiary plans which axe eventually given the. rubber stamp of approval by the Supreme Soviet (theoretically the highest legislative body). Virtually all economic activity in the USSR is included. in the state plan.. The only economic activities of any importance not included are the collective farm market, where the state does not control the price and only indirectly controls the supply, and the disposition by farmers of produce grown .on their individual plots and of income in kind they recetve from. the collectivE farms. In addition to their duties on the Party Presidium, leadixig members of the Party hold government executive posts in the Council of Ministers.. In recent years,. certain individuals who are members of both the Party and Ministerial Presidiums are responsible for several ministries and thereby control whole sectors of the economy. -6- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02: CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 b. The Ministries.. Implementatipn of the state econa~mie pl.as~.s involves two basic operations: (1) allocation of resources to productions and (2) distribution of the output to various uses. These functions are performed by the economic ministries subordinated to the Council of Minister's and by the various staffs attached thereto. The minis- tries are of three basic types:- (1) the ,~.-Union ministries of overriding national significance, which have. no counterparts in the Republics (for example, the Defense Ministry); (2) the Union-Repub- lic ministries (for example, the Ministry of Agriculture of the USSR) each of which hag a counterpart in each of the sixteen constituent republics; and (3)-the Republic Ministries (such as the- various Ministries of I~oea1 Industry), which are concerned with the local affairs of each republic and have no counterpart for the USSR as a whole. Recently there has been a shift in Soviet organizational doctrine from an emphasis on centralization in the Administration of Heavy Industry to limited decentralization, which has been reflected ire;` a transfer of ministries from. All-Union to Union-Republic status. .Each ministry is headed by a council consisting of the Minister and several deputy Ministers and is further divided into several main administrations (for example, for sales, supply', and. production). Historically the Soviet ministerial structure has had two outstanding characteristics: specialization according to productive- activity and proliferation of extra-ministerial control and verification staffs. With the important exception of agriculture, virtually all production of goods and services in the-USSR is carried on directly by state-owned enterprises. Socialized enter- prises account for more than 98 percent of all-industrial production, and practically all banking, transportation, and foreign trade; co- operatives account for only an insignificant part of industrial pro- duction. Education, medical care,. coamiunications, the press, and social services are all controlled by the governmental apparatus. The state distribution syste~i, accounts for practically all internal wholesale trade and for an estimated 85 percent of all retail trade. The free but restricted collective farm market accounts for the remainder. In agriculture, approximately 85 percent of produc- tion is carried out by the kolkhozes, supposedly free associations of the peasantry for the communal cultivation of land assigned for S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T use in perpetuity. Direet production by the state is limited to the state farm. (sovkhoz~. In addition, the state owns and operates the Machine Tractor Stations, which control the entire agricultural tractor park and the bulk of all other agricultural machinery which it rents to the collective farms. Although all productive activity on the collective farm land enters into the state plan, planning in this sector is relatively less precise, owing td the greater diffi- culty of control and the uncertainty of agricultural production. The peasants' attitude of antipathy to a socialized system, in addi- tion to resentment of specific deprivations under it, has added to the poor record of performance. Thus in the agricultural sector the state plans for certain commodities, notably meat and dairy products, have been repeatedly underfulfilled. The only remaining economic activity of any importance which the state simply regulates but does not operate or even plan is the collective farm market. This is an open market where she peasants may sell their surplus produce, which is derived primarily from pri- vate cultivation on individual plots which the collective farm members are permitted to retain. In the collective farm market the state has neither price nor credit controls. Control of the distribution process involves the al- location of land, producer goods, consumer goods, labor, and income. In the USSR all land rights are vested in the state. Agricultural land is granted to the collective farms far use in perpetuity without right of ~,ransfer. Manufacturing and extractive industries, trans- portation, and other enterprises receive use right to land in accord- ance with state plans for these activities. The use right to urban lands for non-industrial purppses is controlled by local government. Most raw materials, the important intermediate pro- ducts, investment goods, and military end items are allocated directly by the Council of Ministers in physical unite. Prices of these items tend to reflect cost of production and serve as the basis for re- imbursement. Each individual producer receives an allocation based upon centrally established input-output norms. Until its absorption into Gosplan in March 1953, the work of making these direct alloca- tions and of establishing the norms was carried out by the State Committee for the Material-Technical Supply of the Econcm~Y, a staff function of the Council of Ministers. Prices are used in some S-E~C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 instances to encourage substitution of one grade of a co~nodity for another (far example, the brown coal from the Mascow basin has. long been s?ld at a subsidized price). In a few instances they perform the traditional role of allocating scarce resources (for example, high rates for railroad transportation). but in general, the- allocat- ing function of prices of industrial goods must be supplemented by administrative- controls. In order to direct labor into the industries and locations necessary to fulfill the state plans, various direct man- power controls are employed, two important devices being the pass- port system and the labor record book (both carried by every Soviet worker). The former limits the worker's geographical movement; the latter requires the approval of the local authority with every ,jab change, and the absence of this approval usually means no housing, The labor union's role is limited. to recruitment, propa- ganda, and administration of social security. Since 1940 the USSR has operated a labor reserve system by which thane 14 to 17 years old are assigned into technical training and then to plants enjoying the highest current priorities. All these direct controls, however, have not been strictly enforced since about 1948. Labor is one factor for which price has remained the primary allocational mechanism. d.. Distribution of Production. The system for distributing consumer goods is complex. Disregarding the collective farm market, most of the food supply produced on the collective farm is brought into-state distribu- tion channels through contractual deliveries, in part at fixed low prices (in effect a tax in kind) or is produced by state-owned food industries- such as fishing and the state farms. Other constnner goods are produced by state enterprises or by producers' cooperatives. Production of the cooperatives is transferred to the state at es- tablished prices. At the retail level the price of consumer goods includes. a high turnover tax calculated to. absorb consumer purchasing power, given the meager supplies of consumer goods available to the population.. In the collective farm market free- prices prevail. The supply, however, is erratic, since it depends on what the peasant saves out. of his income in kind from the collective farm and from production in his private- plot. Since transportation is limited, and since no marketing organization for such produce exists, the peasant is limited to a narrow geographical market. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T Since virtually every Soviet citizen except the collective farmer is on the payroll of the state, the state has direct control of most income. Through the system of taxation and obligatory deliveries the state has a fair degree of control over the income of the collective farm. households. In recent years the state loans (compulsory interest-free loans with a lottery bonus feature) are estimated to have absorbed the equivalent of one month's salary for a1:1 wage earners. The turnover tax also absorbs a con- siderable portion of household income. The state collects a very substantial tax from the profits of the state-owned enterprises. The amortization allowances of the enterprises and the greater part of profits after taxes (which themselves are planned are invested by the enterprises in accordance with the state plan. Only a small fraction of the profits accrues to the manager's fund, which may be used for various worker benefits. Collectively these sources com- prise the largest part of the nation's investment funds, which are then allocated in the All-Union budget. Foreign trade is a state monopoly, which historically has served several purposes; (1~ to isolate the internal market from the external, (2~ to adjust for Soviet deficiency in capital goods and materials and technical services needed for the fulfillment of plans, and (3) to serve as an instrument of Soviet foreign policy. Through the Ministry of State Reserves the state takes control of a large inventory of material and equipment in the USSR. The functions of this inventory are to adjust for planning errors, to compensate for failure to meet production goals, to regulate the flow of resources, to insure against hoarding, and to provide a strategic stockpile. The lifeblood of this vast production and allocation process is information and control. The central planners have a large and comprehensive statistical reporting system. Everything fro~- collective farm beehives to the output of steel plants is re- ported at frequent intervals to the Central Statistical Directorate in Moscow. The control and verification apparatus of the state has three basic parts; the banking system, the verification and punitivh ministries, and special staffs for particular purposes. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 E-G R-E-T zn ad,dttion,. the Cc~unist Party organization constitutes an inde- pendent and parallel control and verification apparatus. The state-owned banking system. controls all long- and short-term credit for every sector of the economy in accordance with floe plan. All working capital and investment accounts- and transactions are controlled with a view to enforcing the plan. The banking system together with the cost accounting apparatus operates the monetary side of the plan to provide what is known in the USSR as '"control by the ruble." The state has a similar monopoly of all banking and credit activities of private individuals. The- specialized verification ministries are ex- emplified by the Ministry of State Control, which has sweeping powers to investigate violations of procedure and general laxity or inefficiency throughout the economic structure. Violations may be dealt with by administrative recommendations to the central organs or by referral to the Procurator General far prosecution, or by both means. The Ministry of Justice and Procurator General are concerned with the violation of economic as well as criminal .and civil law. The Council of Collective Farm Affairs illustrates the special staff for a special purpose. Created after the war to deal with broad problems of agricultural policy and to provide continuous surveillance of the collective farms, the council was dissolved in early 1953? The Soviet extraministerial control staff resembles the regulatory Commission of parliamentary governments except that the former has punitive powers. Finally, the Party acts as an all-pervasive organ of .control and verification, penetrating the government, the secret police, the trade unions, and the collective farms -- in short, every aspect of Soviet life, economic, social, or political. The Party, of course, reports to the Presidium, which controls the entire state apparatus. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T B. European Satellites. In most cases the European. Satellites were brought into the Soviet sphere rather gradually during and after World War II. Mili- tary occupation made it passible for the USSR either to set up puppet governments or to insure dominance by the C~nist Party in the leftist coalitions that controlled these countries. Since 19+8 the governments of all the present Satellites--East Germany, Poland, Czechoslovakia, Hungary, Bulgaria, Albania, and Rumania--have been firmly under Communist control with little organized resistance. The Communist Parties in the Satellites are the primary in- strument for implementing Soviet aims in this area. In addition, various kinds of Soviet personnel operate within the Satellite coun- tries, as inspectors to check production for conformity with Soviet specifications and as economic or commercial missions to maintain close liaison with the appropriate Satellite ministries. Amore direct control is exercised through Soviet ownership of industrial property in these countries, either complete, or jointly with the Satellite government. In the latter case the chairman of the board of directors has generally been a national of the Satellite country, but the general manager has been a Soviet citizen empowered to ne- gotiate agreements and to carry out banking, personnel,. and other administrative transactions. The Council for Economic Mutual Assistance (CEMA) provides the USSR with another mechanism of control over the Satellite economies. CEMA was created in 19+9, apparently in part to counter the psychological effects of the Marshall Plan for Western Europe. Officially its stated purpose is to channel Soviet aid to the "people's democracies" of Eas-~ern Europe and to promote cooperation among "equal partners of the Soviet Bloc." It has a Council and a Secretariat General located in Moscow, to which each country sends permanent delegates, who are typically high officials in the re- spective planning commissions. It seems clear that the CEMA has furthered the economic integration of the Bloc countries and is a potential instrument for forming and administering economic plans Which embrace both the USSR and the European Satellites. In general the European Satellites have already adopted the Soviet pattern of economic organization and techniques of administra- tion. Long-term trade agreements have furthered their integration into the Soviet orbit. I`here is little doubt that the plans of the Satellites reflect the broad goals established by the USSR. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999109/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T C. Communist China. Chinese Communist economic policy is directed toward rapid development of industrial and military power on the Soviet model. The difficulties which the Communists face in achieving their goals for industrialization are considerable. China is predominantly an agricultural country and most of its income comes either from agri- cultural production or from processing and trading in agricultural products. The Communists consider that the present economic organi- zation of society represents a transition period to socialism, in that cooperatives and private enterprises continue to function but under the general direction of the state along with state-operated and joint state and private enterprises. While Communist China. is still far behind the-other countries of the Soviet Bloc in this regard, Communist control over the economy has increased rapidly in the few years since 1949 when the Communists took over the whole of the China mainland. In 1949 the Communists were confronted with an economy which had been strained and disrupted, not only by the preceding four years of civil war but also by the earlier Sino-Japanese war and the loss of Manchuria. From 1945 to 1949, Manchurian output was far below the level that prevailed during the period of Japanese occupa- tion, as a result of the Russian removal of key items of industrial equipment as well as destruction and disorganization during the civil war. A period of hyper-inflation had also had its effect. By the end of 1950 the Chinese economy was subjected to the addi- tional strains of the Korean War and the drastic reduction in trade with non-Communist countries. On the other hand, during the period from 1950 to 1952 China, for the first time since the early 1930ts, experienced the relative political stability of a single government. The Communists also had the benefit of the large investments in heavy industry, transportation, and electric power that the Japanese had made in Manchuria. Over-all output of goods and services increased by 6 percent from 1950 to 1951, by nearly 8 percent from 1951 to 1952, and by 7 percent-from 1952 to 1953? The general increase in output was ac- companied by a reorientation of trade from the West to the USSR. By 1952, output in nearly all sectors of the economy was restored to the highest pre-Communist levels (which in China proper had occurred in 1936, in Manchuria in 1943). Agricultural output was still slightly below the level attained in 1936. In iron and steel production, in railroad transportation, and in the production of military end-items, 1952 output was well above pre-Communist levels. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CfA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R E-T The Communist government exercises an increasing degree of direct control over the economy. According to the communique released by the Central Statistical Bureau: Of the 1952 total value of output of state-owned and private industry, state-owned industry accounted fur 50 percent, ,joint state and privately owned industry for 5 percent, cooperatives for 3 percent, and private indus- try for ~+2 percent . In the producer goods industries, state-operated enterprises produce 80 percent of all output. All railroads, airlines, telecommunications, and most of the shipping is owned by the state; moreover, much privatel,}r owned industrial production is under direct government contract, Little banking is undertaken by other than state banks and then only under strict state supervision. The government also exercises considerable direct control over trade. In 1952 one-half of all trade was carried on by state trading companies or cooperatives, while 80 percent of grain and agricultural products was handled by state trading companies. International trade, which is subject to strict export and import controls, is for the most part handled by state organs. Communist control of agriculture is exercised via a direct control over most trade in agricultural products and also through the political control of Commuxist cadres. Chinese Communist policy relating to the organization of agricultural production may be divided into three distinct stages: land reform, the present mixed policy of encouraging various types of cooperative cultivation, and the collectivization scheduled for the future. The land redistribution program of 19+9-50 enabled the Commu- nists to consolidate their political power with no serious interruption of production. In order to maintain output, rich peasants were not liquidated, although some of them lost part of their land along with those landowners who were completely dispossessed. The program of land reform, involving as it did smaller land holdings-, and bringing about a more equal income distribution, reduced the margin between production and consumption and thus inhibited capital accumulation. This made the peasant more dependent on the government or other sources for credit and assistance. About ~+0 percent of farm house- holds have been organized for some form of ,joint economic action. S-E -C -R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 ~: CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E~-R-E-T About 8 million mutual aid teams have been organized, which, pool draft animals and implements for important field tasks. In 1.952 there were about 4,000 producer cooperatives, a form of association in which land is cultivated jointly and returns aY'e apportioned according to the. land, labor, and equipment contributed. There are only about 23 collective farms in all China. After a period in 1950 when prices continued to rise sharply, a reversal of price movement occurred, and by the end of 1951 the price level for consumer goods was very little above. that prevailing at the end of 1950. Producer goods prices continued to rise during 1951, but by 1952 the price level had, apparently been stabilized. The budget has served as the apparatus for determining the aggregate volume of saving, for there is probably very little private investment. In 1951, expenditures for defense, for invest- ment, and for education and propaganda were double those of 1950. In 1952 military expenditures remained at about the same level, but investment again doubled, while expenditures for education and propa- ganda increased by two-thirds over their 1951 level. About 73 percent of gross national product in 1952 was devoted to consumption, and of the remainder about half went for government expenditures for military forces and administration and the other half for state investment. (See page 24, below for similar data on the Soviet economy.) The grain tax takes between 20 and 25 percent of the total value of the main crops and serves as a fundamental source of government revenue. The urban business taxes; which hit the private trader as well as state enterprises, are increasingly important in the Communist budget, contributing 36 percent of 1953 revenues. Two campaigns in the spring of-1952 against alleged economic vices were important steps in enforcing this tax structure and in consolidating effective control over all economic activity. Problems in balancing their budgets continued until the time of this campaign. Revenue from. state enterprises also increased from 1949 to 1952? The percentage of total revenue derived from state profits doubled between 1950 and 1952, reflecting high profits from industry and also the dominant position of the state in rural-urban trade. The importance of profits of state industrial enterprises also reflects a price structure in which the prices of foodstuffs and raw materials are much lower relative to prices of industrial products than was true before the Sino-Japanese war. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 : CAA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T II. Recent Developments in the Bloc Economies. A. USSR. 1. Political Developments. The death of Stalin in March 1953 was immediately followed by extensive personnel and organizational changes. The locus of power shifted from the absolute and arbitrary dictatorship of a single man, Stalin, to a small group of successors, none of whom has yet achieved Stalin's full powers. Authority now rests in a group of ten men, with a highly uneven distribution of power among them. G.M. Malenkov occupies first place, with leadership in both the Party and Government, followed by N.S. Krushchev who runs everyday party affairs and dictates agricultural policy. The others in the group handle specialized fields such as foreign affairs, trade, military affairs, and so forth. On Stalin's death, the new regime immediately reorganized the government apparatus, consolidating the number of ministries from 52 to 25 and dissolving a number of extraministerial bodies in order to concentrate broad decision-making and executive powers in a small group . During the winter and spring of 1953-54 new ministries gradually emerged, some with.the same functions which they had exercised before Stalin's death, others combined or reorganized along lines fitting more closely with the new policies of the regime. By April 1954 the number of ministries had been raised t-o 46, indicating perhaps the completion of an initial phase of administrative read~ust- ment. The authority of the new Soviet regime remains no less supreme than it was under Stalin. The Soviet political system remains a one-party dictatorship, and the enforced primacy of state interest over that of society continues to color and shape every aspect of Soviet life. There has, however, been a significant change in the manner in which the new regime exercises its power. The regime has taken steps to improve living standards, especially in rural areas, to provide a greater measure of individual security through a more - 16 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 s -E -C -R -E -T strict observance of legality and has reassured the people of a peace- - ful international policy. In addition, the post-Stalin regime has taken steps to broaden its base of support among important social groups --military, managerial,. and intellectuta;l -- by granting them wider prerogatives and by relaxing the rigid pattern of cultural con- formity. The motivation lies less in a fear of popular discontent than in a reinterpretation of the best interests of the regime aaad ways of implementing its long-term goals. 2. Economic Developments. The present regime in the USSR has not changed its traditional policy of placing primary emphasis on the rapid develop- ment of heavy industry and war potential. The new regime has, however, devoted a great deal of its attention and energies to a revision of current ecanomic plans-aimed at speeding up the production. of agri- cultural commodities, especially foodstuffs, .and manufactured consumer goods. Soviet leaders have stated that this goal is to be achieved without decreasing the tempo of heavy industrial development, but defense outlays for military end items and maintenance of the armed farces, which had increased rapidly from 1949 to 1952, have remained at about the same level since then. This modification of Soviet economic programs is designed to overcome the deficiencies in the development of certain sectors of the economy, particularly agri- culture, and to facilitate amore balanced growth of the economy. a. Heavy Industry. Although new lines of emphasis in the economy are intended to raise the output of consumer goods and agriculture, they are not on such a scale as to affect the primary focus of Soviet economic policy of building up the base of heavy industry. The 1954 plan for investment in heavy industry is quite adequate to maintain present growth rates and constitutes over 50 percent of total Soviet investment. b. Defense Expenditures.. Defense expenditures rose rapidly from 1949 to 1952 and then through 1953 and 1954 as planned remained about the same, at a level considerably above that of 1948. The constant rise in expenditures from 1949 through 1952 was-the result of a program of modernization and reequipment of the armed forces. Expenditures leveled off in 1953 S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T and planned expenditures for 1954 remain at about the same level. The Soviet rulers apparently feel that the current size of the armed forces and the current rates of military production are adequate, so that additional resources can now be allocated to other sectors of the economy. c. Agriculture. The growth of Soviet agriculture has lagged consistently behind the growth of Soviet industry throughout the postwar period. Whereas industrial production reached prewar (193$) levels by 1948, production of foodstuffs did not reach maximum prewar levels until 1952. And while industrial production increased 230 percent from 1940 to 1952, according to Soviet statistics, agricultural productionyincluding technical crops, rose by only 10 percent in the same period. The new Soviet leaders have recognized that a continued serious lag in agricul- tural growth, accentuated in.the last three years, could ultimately threaten not only the food requirements of a rapidly growing urban population but also the raw material requirements of an expanding industrial economy and the agricultural export requirements of Soviet foreign trade. In response to this situation the post-Stalin regime has embarked on a program to strEngthen what has now been admitted to be a weak link in the Soviet economy. The main lines of this program. were indicated in the measures announced in the fall-and winter of 1953-54, which call for a sharp increase during the next few years in the production of foodstuffs and agricultural raw materials. The new program modifies some of the more pronounced shortcomings of previous agricultural policies, while leaving basically intact the existing structure of the collective farm system of agriculture. Essentially the new program represents a shift in resources and attention to a heretofore relatively neglected area of Soviet economic development. Responsibility for the lag in agricultural output has rested on (1) the lack of experienced trained personnel; (2) the per- petually antagonistic attitude of the peasants to the collective system; (3) the lack of building materials, equipment and fertilizer; (4) rigid systems of taxation, compulsory state deliveries, and bonus and wage payments which largely negated incentives to produce; and (5) a general lack of attention and guidance by the state and party. - 18 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S E-C-R-E-T The present regime is trying to overcome these deficiencies by (1) channeling greater investment to agriculture in the farm of buildings, equipment, and fertilizer; (2) increasing incentives to produce in both the communal and private sectors by raising the prices paid for obligat.ary deliveries and purchases of same products by the state and by lowering the amounts of obligatory deliver-.ie~s; (3) providing the farms with a larger supply of qualified technicians; ( ) increasing incentives for private production by liberalizing the agricultural taxation system and facilitating .marketing of products; (5) channeling a larger supply of consumer goods and materials to-rural markets; and (6) bringing under culti- vation-vast areas of semi-arid land in the eastern USSR and Central Asia. Through these and other measures the new regime is trying to achieve a sharp upsurge in agriculture in the next two or three years. The success of this effort will determine to a large extent the success of the program to increase consumer goods, which depends heavily on agricultural raw materials. Since the wax, investment in consumer goods industries has been given lowest priority, with requirements for defense and for the reconstruction and rapid development of heavy industry providing the chief determinants of resource allocations. In 1953 the Soviet leaders promised to increase substantially the volume of consumer goods available to the people. The commodities emphasized in the official pronouncements were foodstuffs, textiles, and consumer durables. Subsequently, it appeared that only moderate increases over original plan levels were scheduled for basic foodstuffs, textiles, and footwear, the production of which is limited by the supply of agricultural raw materials. Mueh larger increases are planned for consumer durables, which have traditionally been produced in small quantities. Essentially the implementation of this program requires the reversal of the persistent trend of recent years, which showed the consumption sector of the economy slipping well below plan levels as a result of priority in the allocation of resources to heavy industry and armaments production. -lg- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T The regime has initiated a series of measures to achieve revised consumption goals. Planned investment in the light and food industries and the trade network has been doubled in 1954 over 1953? Heavy industries which have customarily pro- duced consumer durables have been directed to speed up their production of these commodities. Higher priorities have been assigned to consumer goods output in the allocation of resources and services, including transportation. Also the regime is apparently attempting to make more consumer goods available until new productian capacity can be put into operation, by large-scale releases of foodstuffs from stockpiles in 1953 and by increased imports of consumer goods from outside the Bloc. e. Implementation of the Program. In order to provide the necessary resources of man- power and material to implement the new agricultural and consumer goods program, a series of shifts in planning have occurred, by far the most significant of which was the leveling off of defense spending. In addition, in 1953 a number of the grandiose Stalin projects, including the Main Turkmen Canal and the afforestation program, were abandoned as well as other investment projects which were not expected to produce initial returns for several years. In order to cut down overhead costs, a number of organizational and personnel changes have occurred at all levels. Measures are being taken to lower production costs and increase productivity by lowering transport charges, shifting material priorities, decreasing staffs, reweighing wage and bonus payments, and so forth. While there is considerable speculation as to whether these measures are adequate to provide the resources for the agricultural and consumer goods program in the light of 'the large increases planned for heavy industry, there is no doubt that the Soviet leadership is genuinely determined to carry out its new policy, which has been popularly received by a people whose living standards are little better today than they were before World War II or even before the Revolution. B. European Satellites. The economic plans Df all the European Satellites were revised at the same time as those in the USSR. The extent of re- visions varied from country to country, but in most instances they represent some reallocation of resources from industry to agriculture, from heavy industry to light industry for the production of consumer goods, anc{ a decrease in defense expenditures. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/0'2 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E -C -R -E -T C . Communist China. The first Chinese version of a five year plan appeared in 1953. No complete set of targets has been announced in connection with it, but its general goal seems to be a doubling of industrial output by 1957. In 1953, industrial production (excluding handicraft output) was raised by 19 percent over the 1952 level. Efforts under the plan are concentrated on 141 projects for which the Russians agreed to give economic and technical assistance, and of which 91 were new and 50 were under way. There is no evidence in the Chinese Communist Five Year Plan of the greater emphasis placed on output of consumer goods which characterizes policy in the rest of the Bloc. In official Chinese Communist theory, the output of consumer goods will increase along with the over-all development of the economy, but the needs of industrialization are to be met first. If anything, Chinese Com- munist propaganda stresses the need for greater austerity in the coming years rather than the reverse. The existence of planning difficulties appeared with the reduction of 1953 targets for capital construction in the middle of that year, largely because of the inability to acquire the equipment and technical assistance necessary to raise investment by 40 percent over 1952. Not only did the 1953 capital construction program fall short of the goal set for it, but agricultural output also failed to pro- gress as planned, remaining at about the 1952 level. Shortages of vegetable oils developed in the cities as a result of the quantities that were exported. In 1953 the Communists resorted to a program of monopoly purchase of all grain to help solve the problem of supplying the growing urban labor force and to gain complete control over the supply of food. Plans for agriculture call for a sharp increase in the number of producer cooperatives from 4,000 to 14,000 in 1953 and 800,000 by 1957. The private commercial class is already being pressed out of existence by state ownership and heavy taxation. Private industry is already completely dependent upon the state for all important decisions, and the primary emphasis- at present is to turn private enterprises into public-private jointly operated enterprises as well as to organize handicraft shops into producer cooperatives. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T III. National Accounts.. A. Gross National Product.* The total output of goods and services (gross national product) of the combined Soviet Bloc countries in 1953, measured in 1951 dollars,. is estimated at $212 billion. By way of comparison, at the same time the gross national product of the US measured in the same dollars was $353 billion, or larger than that of the entire Bloc by about two-thirds, while the combined output of the US and European NATO powers -- $513 billion -- was nearly two and one-half times grater than that of the Soviet Bloc. The rates at which total production has been increasing in recent years have been higher in the Bloc than in the West, however, as shown in Table 1,~~ with the result that the difference in the level of output will become smaller. By 1953~B1oc output was 37 per- cent above its prewar (1938) level. This ratio, however, averages the much higher level of recovery of the USSR (70 percent above prewar), one of no over-all change in output in the European Satellites (by 1953 they had just regained the prewar level), and a very small increase in the .total output of China. Over the same period (1937 to 1953), total output in .the US, where war-destroyed productive capacity did not have to be replaced, grew at an average annual rate of 6.3 percent to a level more than twice as high as the prewar level. (The implicit com- parison between rates of growth for the US and USSR is somewhat dis- torted in favor of the US, however. For 1937, while the most prosperous year of the late 1930's, still was a year of widespread unemployment. Since 14 percent of the civilian labor force was unemployed in 1937, as compared with approximately full employment in 1953, the US average annual growth rate is overstated, perhaps by about 1 percent . ) During the recent postwar period, on the other hand, the rates of growth of both the Bloc as a whole and the USSR in particular have been quite spectacular. Between 1948 and 1952 the total output of the Bloc increased on the average at 8.4 percent per year, that of the USSR at 9.6 percent annually. The growth of Bloc production is impressive even in view of the fact that it was partly based on non-recurring gains ~ Gross national product is the total value of all goods and services produced in an economy during a given period of time. *~ Table 1 follows on p. 23 S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E -C -R -E -T Table 1 Gross National Product of the Soviet Bloc and NATO Powers by Principal .Areas 1938-53 Billion 1951 US Dollars 1938 1948 1952 1953 Soviet Bloc 155 147 202 212 USSR 74 81 llg 124 European Satellites 45 33 43 45 China ~ 36 ~ 33 J 40 43 NATO Powers ~ 290 423 497 513 us 165 283 340 353 Other ~ 125 140 157 160 a. Total output valued in US prices. b. 1936 estimate. c. 1948 estimate. d. Excluding Turkey and Canada. for example, rehabilitation of war-damaged facilities, accelerated borrowing of Western technology, and conversion of plant and equip- ment from limited military production to full peacetime production. During the same period the total output of the US and NATO powers combined grew at the much lower average rate of 4.1 percent annually, while that of the US was increasing at 5 percent. Since 1848 the relative difference between the volumes of production turned out by the Soviet Bloc and the West has steadily narrowed. Bloc production in 1848 was only about one-third as large as that of the West, whereas by 1953 Bloc output had risen to 41 percent. The improvement in the relative position of the Bloc economies is likely to continue, at least through 1956, while at the same time the absolute differential favoring the West will widen, but at a declining rate. S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E -C -R -E -T The rapid rate of growth of Bloc economies, and especially the Soviet economy, which prevailed until 1952, declined markedly in 1953, from an annual rate of over 10 percent in the USSR for the years 1950-52, to one of 3.7 percent, as a result of the shift in Soviet economic policy described above (in Section II). The rate of growth is expected to rise again, however, as the new policy is put into effect and to level off in the USSR at about 6.0-6.5 per- cent annually for the period through 1956. Even. this lower rate is substantially higher than the long-run average rate of 3 to ~+ percent expected in the US. B. Gross National Product by Use. Comparisons of gross national product and long-run growth rates, however, are indicative only in a very broad sense of the aggregate productive capacities of the economies concerned. The internal composition of production is more instructive in revealing the industrial areas of strength and growth and showing how the output of the society is distributed among various component groups. Table 2 shows the effects of the emphasis placed in the USSR on investment and defense, especially the latter in the postwar period and indicates how the expense of each fell on consumption. Division of Gross National Product by End Use USSR, Selected Years, 1938-53; US, 1953 ussR a/ us Use 1938 1948 1952 1953 1953 Consumption 71.5 65.7 58.9 57.8 66.7 Administration 2.5 3.0 2.5 2.5 2.6 Defense 8.3 9.1 13.0 12.9 13.6 Investment 17.7 22.2 25.6 26.8 17.7 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 a. The Soviet data assume that one.-half of the turnover tax is a non-cost element. S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 `. CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E -C -R -E -T Investment and defense together accounted for 39 percent of total production in 1952 compared with 31 percent in 1948. The slower tempo of the rearmament program during 1952 and 1953 shows up in the increased share of resources devoted to investment; an increase in the relative position of consumption is expected for 195+? From the amount, in dollars, of gross national product that flows to consumption uses, it is possible to derive a very rough notion of relative living standards in the two countries. Dividing the dollar figure by the total population yields a measure of $319 (in 1951 'US prices) as the average volume of goods consumed per person in the USSR, as compared with $2,192 in the US. The com- parison is extremely rough, for differences in the quality of consumer goods, variety, ease of acquisition, and other such con- siderations, all of which favor the US, axe not reflected. The stress on consumer goods and a higher standard of living contained in the recent policy shift is likely to bring only small changes in the relative importance of the various uses of total out- put. It is anticipated that by mid-1956 consumption will account for about 59 percent of total output and defense 11 percent, compared with 58 percent and 13 percent~respectively~in 1953? C. Gross National Product by Industry of Origin. -The relative importance of various broad categories of .industry in the USSR, and the changing industrial structure over time axe indicated in Table 3.~ .The emphasis placed by the Soviet planners on industry (that is, production of finished prod.uoer goods, consumer goods, and military end items) and construction is reflected in the increasing relative importance of these two groups. The relative importance of industry in the USSR today is little different from that of .the US. The greater relative importance of transportation in the USSR is a reflection of the larger land mass over which the interrelationships among various activities of the economy must be integrated by means of a transport network. Both the larger relative importance of agriculture and the smaller relative importance of trade and service in the USSR are sometimes cited as a reflection of the lower stage of economic development of the USSR as compared with the US. As the per capita volume of output of a maxket economy increases, the relative importance of primary and secondary ~- Table 3 follows on p. 26. ' S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T Table 3 Gross National Product by Industry of Origin USSR, Selected Years, 1938-53; US, 1953 Pe rcent USSR 1938 19+8 1952 1 US 953 1953 Industry 25.3 -28.2 35.9 x+2.3 39.9 Agriculture X6.0 36.1 30.9 19.3 5?~+ C onstruction 3.5 ~-.5 5.2 6.2 4.9 Transportation 5.5 6.7 7.6 8.8 6.0 Communications 0.5 0.9 O.g 1.1 1.3 Trade ~- . 5 6.5 5.2 6.0 16.5 Services 1~-.4 17.1 1~+.3 16.3 25.9 Total 99.3 100.0 loo.o loo.0 99 9 . industries (that is~agriculture and industry) typically declines, whereas that of the tertiary industries (public utilities and the service industries) increases. Whether the relatively iuip ortant role of the tertiary industries in an advanced market economy ever will characterize the planned Soviet economy, it is difficult to say. In any event, stages of economic development in two economies controlled by such diverse motivating forces should probably not be compared. IV. Economic and Industrial Base. A glance at the resources within the borders of the Soviet Bloc is enough to establish the fact that the USSR has at its disposal a for- midable productive potential. The Bloc comprises the "heartland" of the Eurasian land mass, with a population of over 800 million, as com- pared to 160 million in the US and over 500 million in all of North America and Western Europe. The Bloc is entirely self-sufficient in food. Every governmental resource is being devoted to the expansion of its heavy industry; moreover, the Bloc possesses nearly all the raw materials required to keep that industry alive. The Satellite economies have been ruthlessly integrated with that of the USSR in an effort to compensate for all weaknesses in the Soviet industrial machine. - 26 - S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E -C -R -E -T The production of basic economic goods and services in the Soviet Bloc, however, falls considerably short of the levels achieved in the US and its Western Allies (that is, the other NATO powers together with Spain and Western Germany . In grain, the Soviet Bloc produces about the same output as the Western Allies and exceeds the US output. Meat production in the US is four times that of the USSR, while the entire Soviet Bloc produces little more meat than the Western Allies. The US and Western Allies outstrip the USSR at least ~+ to l in energy production. The Soviet Bloc is far behind the US and Western Allies in the production of metals, and munitions expenditures are more than twice those of the USSR. In making such comparisons, however, differences in patterns of production and habits of consumption in the two countries must be borne in mind. In considering munitions expenditures, for example, the US .reveals a strong tendency to sub- stitute machines for men in its armed forces; close tolerance s throughout its materiel are required; and the ratio of materiel to numbers in the armed forces is large. In the USSR close tolerances are required only when absolutely necessary for efficiency, and materiel expenditure per capita is much lower than in the US. A. Population and Manpower. Collectively the Soviet Bloc today includes two of the three most populous nations in the world, the USSR and Communist China.. A description follows of the salient features of the population and labor force of-the three broad geographical areas, the USSR, the European ?~atellites, and Communist China. In mid-1953 the USSR, with 212 million people, ranked third among the countries of the world, its population being 30 per- cent larger than that of the US. Since 1939 the population of the USSR has expanded both as the result of annexations of new territories and of natural population increases. During the war, losses of man- - power in battle were balanced by gains from new territories acquired. Since the war, population gains have resulted from natural increase. .Apart from the effects of annexations and war, the Soviet population is increasing at a relatively high natural rate, altYiough one which is only slightly higher than that of the US at present. It is estimated that ~,n the decade after 19+7 the population will increase by an average of about 1.7 percent a year. While birth and death - 27 - S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E ~ -R -E -T. rates have both declined, the excess of births over deaths has re- mained large and the population relatively young. While in 1939, 36 percent of the population was under 15 years of age, in 1953 the proportion had declined only to 34 percent. The Soviet government has tried to sustain a high birth rate and has succeeded in reducing the death rate. Medical care is free and approximately as adequate as that in the US, ,judging by the ratio of doctors to the total population. Abortion was proscribed in 1935, and in the following year the government issued a com- prehensive pro-natalist decree. This measure (a) strengthened the law prohibiting abortions, (b) provided annual allowances for mothers of large families, (c) made it more difficult to secure divorces, and (d) provided for expansion of nurseries and kinder- gartens. Even before World War II the Soviet population was characterized by a surplus of women. This imbalance was intensified during the war years and is expected to prevail for scene time to came. The drawing of women into the labor force, especially into skilled occupations and professions, has long been a policy of the USSR, with the result that today over one-half of the female popu- lation between the ages of 15 and 65 years is employed outside the home. By law, women receive equal pay for equal work. In 1939 about 57 percent of Soviet citizens were between the ages of 15 and 60 years; the relative importance of this group has increased to nearly 59 percent in 1953 and will probably con- tinue to grow for several years more. This age bracket supplies about 90 percent of the civilian labor force and armed services. Almost 98 percent of the men and 60 to 70 percent of the women in this group are in the total labor force . Estimates of the size of the lobar force in the USSR vary depending on how inclusive they are. The official Soviet data usually exclude workers in private employment, at forced labor, and in the armed forces or on collective farms, but include all others. The importance of the supply of forced labor .(political prisoners and unrepatriated prisoners of war) is indicated by estimates of its size, which range from 3.5 to 12 million people. Excluding the .armed forces (which are estimated at 4.4 million in 1953) and forced labor, the size of the civilian labor force in mid-1953 was estimated at 94 million people, of which agricultural employment accounted for more than half (52 million). S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02': CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E -C -R -E -T The decline in the importance of agricultural employment in the total labor force reflects the- stress on industrialization of past Soviet policy. In the immediate future, however, it appears likely that this trend will be reversed and the number cif agricultural workers will increase as part of the recently announced policy emphasis on increased quantities of consumer goods. It is interesting to note. that the new goals for food output necessitate the transfer of a large body of technical personnel from industrial to agricultural communities. During the earlier period of rapid industrialization the agricultural sector lost a large fraction of its youth to industrial centers and consequently now suffers a shortage of essential skilled workers. Despite the larger total population, the nonagricultural labor force of the USSR is somewhat smaller than that of the US f42 as compared with 48 million in 1953), but the relative importance of employment in manufacturing, mining, and. construction is approxi- mately the same in each (about 40 percent). On the other hand, the greater geographic distances involved in the operation of the Soviet economy and the tremendous drain they impose on Soviet pro- ductive resources are revealed in the fact that 12 percent of the Soviet nonagricultural labor force is employed in the transportation industries alone, as compared with 9 percent of the US total which is employed in both transportation and public utilities. In nonagricultural employment the declining impartance of unskilled workers mirrors the effects of expanded technical educational programs. The compulsory labor reserve training program for youth was sharply curtailed in recent years as the country broadened the educational base of the entire population. Plans for 195+, however,. indicate an expansion of the labor reserve training program, with emphasis on agricultural training. Summary data on population and employment in the USSR are given in Table ~+.~ Table follows on p. 30. - 2g - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E -C -R -E -T Table 4 Population and Employment in the USSR a~ as of 1 January 1939, 1g47, 1950 and 1953 ulation Po ~9 19+7 1950 1953 p Total b~ 170 lgl 200 210 Males 82 88 g2 g8 Females 89 103 108 112 Civilian Employment c~ Total b/ 76 84 87 go d/ Agricultural Labor ~+6 52 50 ~+8 Nonagricultural Labor b~ 30 32 37 42 Skilled 6 6 9 Unskilled 24 24 28 Engineering, Technical, and Professional 3 5 Industry, Mining and Construction ~~ 12 18 a. According to current boundaries. b. Columns-not additive, because of rounding. c. Excluding military personnel. d. As compared with g4 million in mid-1953. This apparently unreasonably large increase results from the inclusion of labor that previously had been excluded as forced. e. Includes skilled, unskilled, and technical and professional labor. S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/0'2 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T 2. European Satellites. The population of the European Satellites is estimated at less than half (43 percent) that of the USSR, or about 92 million people. For the decade from 1947 through 1956 the population increase is expected to be about 7.3 percent or less than half of the expected rate of iBerease for the USSR over the same period. On the basis of these estimates, the Satellites as a group will attain the prewar population level of about 95 million by 1956. Rates of increase for the individual Satellites range from 0 in the Soviet Zone of Germany to 22 per thousand in Albania. The armed forces of the Satellites are estimated roughly to have numbered 2 million in 1953 as compared with 4.4 million on military duty in the USSR. The civilian labor force of 43 million in the Satellites as shown in Table 5,~' is nearly evenly distributed between agri- cultural and nonagricultural employment, the preponderance of industrial workers in Czechoslovakia, East Germany and Hungary balancing the preponderance of agrarian employment in the others. Agriculture has been losing workers to nonagricultural pursuits since 1947; whether or not this trend continues will depend on the implemen- tation of the new policy aiming at expanded output of consumer goods and food. Amore extensive employment of women is also anticipated. Whereas 66 percent of the nonagricultural labor force of the USSR is composed of unskilled labor, the latter accounts for over 70 percent of the total in the Satellites. On 1 January 1953 there were. 4.2 million skilled workers. in the Satellites, which is to be compered with 8.7 million in the USSR. There were 2.1 million in the engineering, professional, and technical group in the Satellites and 5.4 million in the USSR. 2'ne European Satellites are adopting the system of vocational training which has been evolved in the USSR. Under pressure for more highly trained personnel, they axe also accelerating personnel training by shortening the time before graduation. The training system is expected to double the supply of skilled labor and of engineering, professional, and technical personnel between 1947 and 1957? ~ Table 5 follows on p. 32. - 31 - S -E -C -R-E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E -C -R -E -T Table 5 Population and Employment in the European Satellites 1 January 1947 and 1953 Industry, mining, and construction 9 13 3? C ommunist China. Until 1953 there had never been a census in China. A preliminary announcement of the first census indicates that China's population was about 580 million in 1953, 20 percent higher than a previous official estimate of 487 million in 1950. For the next decade, population growth will probably depend on the degree to which the high death rate can be controaled, for it seems likely that the birth rate will remain high and relatively stable. If the country succeeds in its program for economic development and improved public health services, the growth rate might reach as high as 1.5 percent per year; with a slower rate of development, however, the population growth might not exceed 1 percent per year. S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T The age distribution of the population is determined by the birth and death rates. China with its high birth and death rates has a younger population than the major industrial countries of the world. Specific information on this subject is, unfortunately, not available. One estimate, resulting from surveys, indicates that 37 percent of the population is under 15 years old, 60 percent is between 15 and 65 years, and only 3 percent is over 65 years. The sex ratio has been estimated at 110-males to 100 females. China possesses more than adequate military manpower. Although the majority of the Chinese people live in rural areas, the total urban population is among the largest in the world. In China, about 87 million people live in cities of more than 10,000 population. In the US in 1950, about 80 million people lived in cities of equivalent size. Of a total labor-force estimated at 278 million to 329 million workers in. 1953, about 85 percent (233 million to 277 mil- lion were rural workers. Most of these, or about 75 percent (210 million to 250 million) of the total labor force, were farm workers. Farm labor is difficult to classify in China, since much of the labor is seasonal or part-time. For instance, most of the 18 million fishermen on inland lakes, rivers, and ponds probably are part-time farmers. From 20 to 25 percent of the labor force is nonagricultural, only a small part of which (possibly 3 million to ~+ million is employed in modern-type industry. In addition to this, there are probably about 20 million workers in the handi- craft trades. Available material indicates that skilled labor is as scarce as common labor is abundant. In a few categories of top level engineers and scientists there is a limited supply of foreign-trained Chinese, but in the fields needed for the development of heavy industries the supply is wholly inadequate for the proposed expansion. To remedy this lack of trained personnel, the Chinese axe adopting the system of adult schools, training on the job, and vocational high schools common to the Soviet Bloc. Higher education also has been expanded, with a shift from liberal arts to technical training in colleges. The demands upon trained manpower, however, are expected to be so great as to provide a serious deterrent to the successful com- pletion of the plans. S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E -C -R -E -T B. Agriculture. Agriculture presents a unique and complex picture in the Soviet Bloc countries. Of the approximately 800 million people living within the Bloc, about 70 percent are dependent on agri- culture for their support. With its variety of climate and soil, the Bloc can grow every crop known in the temperate and subtropical zones. Farms range from the fairly modern state and collective farms of the USSR, often encompassing thousands of acres, to the tiny, hand-cultivated plots of China. At the present time, production is sufficient to permit a subsistence diet, some exports, and at least limited state reserves of food. The situation in agriculture is discussed below for each of the major areas. The USSR occupies one-sixth of the total land surface of the world, but little more than 10 percent of this area can be classed as arable, and of this arable land only about 65 percent is cultivated. Because of unfavorable climate, much of the land is un- suitable for agriculture, and most of the arable land is found in the "fertile triangle" which extends from Leningrad to Odessa to Lake Baikal. Sown acreage increased from 127 million hectares (1 hectare equals 2.x+7 acres) in 1930 (1930 boundaries) to about 157 million hectares in 1953 (1953 boundaries}. This expansion has taken place both through territorial acquisitions and through the extension of the cultivated area into regions of erratic production. There is hardly a crop of the temperate and subtropical zones that is not grown in the USSR. Grains dominate the crop pattern. Potatoes, sugar beets, cotton, flax, feed crops, and sunflower seed are the most important non-grain crops. Agriculture, especially food production, has been and will continue to be an area of weakness in the Soviet economy. Anew agricultural program, designed in part to bolster food production, aims to bring 13 million hectares of new land into cultivation and envisages a considerable increase in the investment program for agri- culture. It apparently is recognized by the new leaders that the continued failure of food output to exceed population growth or to keep pace with the rest of the economy constitutes a future threat to the economic welfare of the Soviet people and to the strategic position of the Soviet state . -3~+- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E -C -R -E -T Soviet agricultural policy has been the main obstacle to increasing production. Since the Bolshevik Revolution a vicious struggle leas been waged between the Communists and the peasantry. Following the disastrous attempts of the Communists to collectivize the peasantry forcibly in the early 1920's, agriculture enjoyed a period of relative independence and prosperity. But in 1928 the USSR undertook -to eliminate the strange paradox that "capitalism existed in the village alongside socialism in-the city," with a vigorous renewal. of the collectivization program. By 1940, 20 million farm households, constituting 97 percent of the peasant population, had been amalgamated into 236,000 collective farms. Further axaa,lgation reduced the number of collective farms to 94,000 by 1953? At present, collective farms account for over 90 percent of total Soviet agricultural production, state farms accounting for most of the remainder. State farms are operated by the state, with the farmers being paid fixed wages. C ollective farms represent a pooling of the land and labor-resources of many small peasant farms. Theoretically, a collective is a democratic institution, governed by charter, 'but the obligations required of the farmers are such that the collective has became merely a tool whereby the state not only controls the peasantry but also assures itself of the major portion of agricultural production. each worker is paid according to the amount and type of work performed, measured in "labor days," the value of which depends upon the productivity and income of the indi~ridual collective. Each household has a private garden plot and the right to maintain a specified number of livestock. Because of its capitalistic nature, the garden plot and privately owned live- stock have been a primary source of concern on the part of the regime. The eventual liquidation of rural capitalism, with the resultant complete dependence of the peasant upon the income of the collective farm, is a goal of the Communist Party of the USSR. As a source of savings, Soviet agriculture during the past two decades has been forced to carry a considerable portion of the burden of the industrialization of the country. Extensive mechani- zation, use of mineral fertilizers, irrigation, and improved agro- techniques have resulted in only modest increases in over-all agricultural production during the last 15 years. The output of certain industrial crops has increased, however, reflecting the special emphasis the government .has placed on them. Sugar production has decreased from 2.48 million metric tons in 1938 to 2.3 million metric tons in 1952, and cotton has increased from 731,691 metric tons S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C -R-E-T in 1938 to 874,000 metric tons (ginned basis) during the same period. Grain production increased slightly from 88.2 million metric tons in 1938 to 91.2 million tons in 1952, then declined to 80.7 in 1953. Production of potatoes, vegetables, and livestock, however, lagged seriously and has not kept. pace with the growth of the population. As a result of great losses suffered during the collectivization period of the early 1930's and as a result of World War II, production in sane sectors such as livestock (chiefly cows) is even less than it was in 1g28. Mechanization released millions of workers for other industries. Machine Tractor Stations (MTS's) were set up to service the needs of the collective farms. Tractors in the MTS's increased from 66,000 15-horsepower units in 1930 (1930 boundaries) to 1 million 15-horsepower units in 1952 (1952 boundaries). Production of other agricultural machinery also increased during this period. The large increases in agricultural output the Russians had envisioned through mechanization, however, did not materialize, because of the inefficient use of the machines. In 1950 the output of work per 15-horsepower unit was only about the same as in 1937, despite marked technological improvements. Use of chemical fertilizers has increased from 228,000 metric tons in 1828 (1828 boundaries) to about 4 million metric tons in 1952 (1952 boundaries). Although during the 1952-53 consumption year the available food supply in the USSR was sufficient to provide about 2,800 calories daily per capita, over 65 percent of the food base is represented by grains. There is a paucity of meat and dairy products, which com- prise less than 5 percent of the diet. During the past few months, significant shifts in agricultural policy in the USSR have occurred. The struggle for the immediate liquidation of the private garden plats has been relaxed temporarily, and production of livestock and vegetables is being encouraged by a series of measures, including the following: a. A greater emphasis on material incentives: procure- ment prices for livestock products and vegetables have been increased, takes on private plots have been lowered considerably and slight tax exemptions granted to encourage the farmers to obtain livestock. b. Investment in machinery necessary for the cultivation of vegetables has been increased. -36- S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 ": CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E -C -R -E -T c. Agricultural loans to provide more buildings and barns on the collective farms. d. Individual responsibility,. especially on the part of tractor drivers, designed to increase machine productivity. e. Improvement in agro-techniques -- more chemical fertilizers, improved seed stock, and more agricultural and live- stock specialists. In general, it can be said that the USSR produces sufficient food-and industrial crops for its own use, given a low standard of living. Despite the noted insufficiencies,~the agri- cultural economy has risen from a half-primitive to a fairly modern status since 1928. Sown acreage has just about reached a peak, and the USSR proposes to achieve subsequent increases in production by increasing yields through a greater use of chemical fertilizers, by greater mechanization, and by irrigation and improved agro-techniques. With appropriate priorities the USSR may be able within the next 5 or 6 years to achieve partially its goals of providing more and varied food to the populace and sufficient raw materials to the industrial plant. 2. European Satellites. The transformation of farming in Eastern Europe from small independently owned plots to large socialist enterprises in the form of collectives and state farms has been a primary aim of the Communist governments established siy~ce World War II. The rate and extent of socialized farming, however, varies considerably among the Satellites. The percent of agricultural land farmed by tY~e socialist sector ranges from approximately 18 percent in East Germany to about 60 percent in Bulgaria. Agriculture has presented the Communist governments with the most thorny problems in their attempt to nationalize the production facilities of the Satellite economies. In implementing their ambitious industrialization programs, the Satellites are dependent upon agriculture to supply needed manpower and a large share of the exports required to finance imports of machinery and raw materials. The methods used by governments to release agri- cultural manpower to industry and obtain a sizable share of the indigenous production have been compulsory delivery quotas and - 37 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E -C -R -E -T collectivization. This policy has had the over-all effect of depressing agricultural production despite the provision for increased output in the plan. Notwithstanding Communist concern for increased production, agricultural output has not yet attained prewar levels. Lack of natural and chemical fertilizers, shifts of population, and the general apathy of the peasantry brought on by collectivization contribute to low productivity. Grains dominate the crop pattern, although con- siderable emphasis is being given to industrial crops, mainly sugar beets. As a direct result of government policies and achrerse weather conditions, livestock numbers in the Satellites, like crop production, have not reached prewar levels. Numbers of the primary meat-producing animals, cattle and swine, have suffered especially. Slaughter weights are also considerably below the prewar level. As a result a serious shortage exists for the industrial population in meat, fats; and dairy products. The primary emphasis of the recently adopted "new course" as it pertains to agriculture is placed on improving animal husbandry. The mechanization of agriculture has been emphasized in the Satellites, but with slight success. Numbers of tractors and complementary equipment have increased, blot not to the extent. called for in the plans. To foster and support collectivization, the mechanical draft power base must be increased. This fact was re- vealed in the self-criticism contained in the recent announcements by most of the Satellites of the "new course" for agriculture. Increased emphasis will now be given to supplying agriculture with more machinery to relieve the labor and draft paver shortage during the next 2 to 3 years. The immediate outlook for an increase in agricultural production and food supply in the Satellites is not very favorable, despite the fact that investments and incentive goods are to be increased and compulsory delivery quotas reduced. Cereals will con- ? tinue to constitute the major share of the diet of the population; and meat, fats, and oils will remain in short supply. - 38 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/0~~~1~4 ~t~P79-01093A000600060003-4 3. C ommunist China. Chinese agriculture is characterized by too many people on too little land, under-capitalization, intensive cultivation, and primitive technology. At least 80 percent of the 580 million people in China live on the land. The arable land of China probably does not exceed 357 million acres, or 16.7 percent of the total Viand area, and the cultivated area is estimated at 272 million acres. Thus there is Somewhat less than 0.5 acre of cultivated land per person.. To increase yields, much of the cultivated land is irrigated,.. Cereal grains, potatoes, and other foods derived from plants con- stitute 85 to 90 percent of the total food supply. In most areas of China, little is provided beyond the minimum daily caloric intake necessary for survival, and the diet is usually deficient in one or more of the nutritive elements essential to health. Chinese agri- culture, moreover, is extremely susceptible to the vagaries of nature. Much of the agricultural production is concentrated in river low- lands, where it is subject to floods. Drought frequently occurs in the plains of North China, typhoons often ravage the coastal areas, insect pests are numerous, and insecticides are virtually unknown. The Chinese Communist "land reform" program has been a revolution from above, organiz@d in the villages by cadres of pro- fessional Communist revolutionaries. As a result of this "reform" the average size of the Chinese farm has been slightly reduced, and the acquisition of capital equipment has become even more difficult than before. The Communists have encouraged several forms of mutual cooperation in agriculture. The cooperative forms range from seasonal pooling of labor with no change in ownership of land or implements to joint farming of pooled land holdings with common ownership of some. implements and draftpower. Ownership of the land even in all cooperative forms except the collective is still retained by the individual. The burden of the agricultural tax in kind (levied at progressive rates) is believed to be heavy. I~t is estimated that 30 million metric tons of grain are collected in taxes each year and 10 million tons in addition through the compulsory purchase program. This represents one of the most important sources of income to the state: the grain tax provides the food for the. cities and the armed forces, and the principal source of foreign exchange . It is believed that the agricultural sector accounts for as much as 75 percent of the exports of Communist China, the bulk of which is used to pay for imports of capital goods from other Soviet Bloc countries. -39- S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S-E-C-R-E-T The Chinese Communists, however, have two solid achieve- ments to their credit: (a) they have energetically continued certain Nationalist-initiated flood control and irrigation projects, such as the Hwai River project, and have begun others, with a consequent increase in the total irrigated area, and (b) they have improved the transportation system so that surpluses can be shifted to deficit areas.. In 1952, production of the major agricultural crops approxi~ mated prewar levels. Table 6 shows the production of major crops in Communist China, 1949-52. Production of Major Crops in Communist China 1949-53 Thousand Metric Tons 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 Grains ~ 104,310 107,_810 106,840 112,361 111,786 Potatoes ~ 24,500 28,887 31,490 34,221 31,035 Cotton ~ 370 529 653 618 724 a. Grains consist of rice paddy , wheat, oats, corn, millet, sorghum and other grains, kaoliang, and barley. b. Potatoes are approximately 85 percent sweet potatoes and are not on a grain-equivalent basis. C. Cotton as shown here is on a ginned basis. Collectivization of agriculture remains the explicit objective of the Chinese Communist Party. Apparently it will be delayed for some time, almost certainly until the next Five Year Plan, which should begin in 1957? One must presume that the cost of collectivization in lost production and in human lives would be even more appalling in China than in the USSR. In attempting to Increase the productivity of Chinese agriculture the Chinese Communists face a difficult problem. With the exception of irrigation and flood control measures, the Chinese Communist actions to date probably have tended to aggravate rather - 40 - S-E-C-R-E-T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 S -E -C -R -E -T than to ameliorate the basic difficulties. It is highly unlikely that the planned increases in production over the next few years will be achieved. Also, it is doubtful whether the Chinese Communists will have available the resources necessary for mechanisation fox a good many years, perhaps a decade. Unless its position in natural resources improves greatly, it is highly unlikely that in the near future China will be able to support the degree of mechanization of agriculture which prevails in the USSR. C. Industry. The development of the industrial base of the USSR and especially of large-scale industry has been the primary goal of the Soviet planners. As the Satellites and China were brought into the Soviet orbit, a similar goal emphasized their industrial development. The pattern followed has initially placed greatest importance and highest priority on heavy industry and producer goods as a means toward the end of ultimate self-sufficiency and industrial and military power. In the USSR the 1930's were devoted to the accumu- lation of basic capital equipment, especially through imports, with concomitant emphasis on technical training of the labor force. The USSR may now be in a position to go forward with rather more balance in the production of consumer and capital goods and with primary reliance upon their own resources. The future pattern can be expected to show relatively more emphasis on the development of basic materials, including energy,? required to support their own industrial machine. The current "new course" indicates a special effort to equip and expand consumer goods industries in the immediate future, a change which may prove to be a temporary political expedient, or an evolutionary shi~'t toward consideration of consumer. welfare. In the following sections the industrial base of the Bloc will be described under the headings of energy, metals, building materials, chemicals, manufacturing, and military end items. Table 7~- shows trends in the production of selected commodities together with a comparison with US output. 1. Energy. The potential energy resources of the Soviet Bloc are adequate to support sizable increases in industrial capacity on a long- term basis. Coal is the main source of energy of the Bloc countries. ~ Table 7 follows on p. ~+2. S -E -C -R -E -T Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 Approved For Release 1999/09/02 :CIA-RDP79-01093A000600060003-4 W U ~~ MI O .-1 ON~Mi~~ ~ Ol ~ ri ~~~~~ ~ ~~~~ o,cp~~ooo 0 H H ~ H ~ O ~. ~ v ~ 2qqf ~ ~ ~ Sc~~ .q~q O SyW.~~ ?ayyC~ ra N ~ ai ~1 O cd ... S-i ~ H cd ~ agg7 cd al N ~' ~ ~~a? ~ or~az ~