THE RECENT RECORD IN SOVIET ECONOMIC GROWTH: CHAPTER V EXTERNAL IMPACT OF SOVIET ECONOMIC POWER

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
K
Document Page Count: 
131
Document Creation Date: 
November 16, 2016
Document Release Date: 
January 7, 2000
Sequence Number: 
1
Case Number: 
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1.pdf6.3 MB
Body: 
Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 sim Ram= RECORD IN SOVIET ECONOMIC GROWN CHAP= V EXTERNAL IMPACT OF SarZET ECONOMIC POWER STATI NTL Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 ' Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 ? 1. Introduction 211BIE OF CONTENTS IX. Trade as an Ideological Weapon A. Laying the Foundation B. Fashioning the Weapon PINE 1 5 5 9 I. Trade with the Communist Bloc A. The Institutions of the Socialist World Market 0 0 ? ? 0 ? 14 14 1. Insulation of the Domestic Economy . 2. Foreign Exthange Bale and Bloc Foreign Trade Prices 9 ? ? OOOOOOOOO a. Nature of Bloc Trade Pricing 16 Practice ......... ? . ? ? b. Historical Course of Bloc Trade 16 Prices 18 3. The Exchange Bate . * ...... 19 4. Non-Commercial Transactlons B. Trade with lasterniWirope: Iron the Stick to the Carrot 29 1. The Period of the Stick , .. 29 2. The Period of the Carrot 2 ? ? 32 3. Economic Assistance ? . . .. 9 9 0 12 34 4. Wade 36 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 C. Trade with China: From the Carrot to the Stick 39 W. Trade mith the Free World . . . . . ......... 43 A. The Traditional Pattern 43 1. UnclawagingCWeendity Composition of Trade with Industrial West 43 2. Preference for Predictable Markets 0 i . . 45 3. Chronic Problems of Finance ... . . . . . 46 D. The Economic Offensive . ? ? ? ..... . .. 0 48 %able* 1. 2. Distribution of Soviet Foreign Trade 1950, 1955, and 1961 Fbreign Exchange Rates for Commercial Transactions for Currencies of the Soviet Bloc 1954-60 and 1961-62 20 3. Foreign Exchange Rate for Non.4ommercia1 Transactions for Currencies of the Soviet Bloc 28 4. Soviet Economic Credits and Grants Extended to the European Satellites 1945.4962 35 3. Soviet Trade with the Europeanfttellites 195541 . 37 6. sovvit Share in European Satellite Trade 3953, 1935, 3960, and 1965 38 7, Soviet Trade mith Communist China 1950-1961 41 3. USSR Trade mith Underdeveloped Countries in 1961 ? ? 55 9. Economic Credits and grants Ektenkied 1talte USSR to Underdeveloped Countries, January 3951962. 56 10. Distribution of Soviet Pbreign Trade in 1961 and Aid mita Free World Underdeveloped Countries in 1954-62. 57 Approved For Release 2000/04/1 qj IA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 ' Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 pp.ndix Tables 11. Geographic Distribution of Soviet Foreign Trade . . . ? 60 12. CommootttyCiomposition of Soviet Mports, 1955-1961 . . 63. 13. Commodity Composition of Soviet ImPorts, 305-1961 . . 63 14. Commodity Composition of Soviet Exports to European Satellites, 1955-1961 , 8 ? ? . 65 150 Commodity Composition of Soviet Imports From European Satellites" 1955-3961 67 16. Commodity Composition of Soviet Exports to COmmunIst China, 19554961 69 17. Commodity Composition of Soviet Imports from Comenultst China, A955-1961 71 18. Commodity Composition of Soviet Exports to Industrial West, 19554961 73 19. CommodityCompcsition of Soviet Imports from Industrial West, 1955-1961 75 20. Commodity Composition of Soviet Exports to Underdeveloped Countries, 1955-1961 76 21. Commodity Composition of Soviet Imports from the Underdeveloped Countries, 19554961 77 22. Trends in FOreign Trade Between the USSR and Selected Free World Countries, 1955-1961. . 76 Selected Bibliography 79 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18: CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 CHAPTER IT External Xinct of Economic Power betroduction Upon completion of its post-ear industrial recovery the ISSSB emerged from the econcadc isolation that bad characterized its behavior through most of its history and since the mid-1950's has increasingly participated in the world economy. The con- tinued emphasis given to economic growth by the Soviet leaders can be explained in terms of their desire to achieve economic, mud especially technologic independence of the West. By the mid-1950's the Soviet were themselve using up-to-date techni- gees to produce the raw materials, fuel and equipment necessary for the sectors of industry which they deemed most important. Since they he. already achieved the basic economic independence ehich vas the goal of their earlier autarkical policies, they mere now prepared to shift from an international econaaic peliay that had been essentially passive and defensive to one ehich was active and aggressive. Wbereas in the pre war period they bad imported in order eventually to eliminate the necessity for imports, in the post ear period they attained aufficient strength to engage on an inereasiegey large scale in Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 trade for political purposes in order to enhance their influence or achieve some noneconomic goal in some other part of the world. The increasing use of interna'tional economic relations as a tool of Soviet international policy does not, of course, imply that the domestic economy had attained complete economic and technological independence of the West. On the contrary, the USSR today must import not only certain industrial materials of strategic significance, but, most important, It continues to be dependent on Western technological advances in many industrial sectors. And in the fields of agriculture and consumer goods the technological lag is greatest. Despite 4 costly and venerable program for the development and production of synthetics, the USSR still is dependent on imports of natural rubber for industry and. transport. A primary goal of the present plan period, the expansion of the chemical industry, is dependent for its success on imports of Western chemical equipment which, embodying most recent technology, serve as prototypes to be copied, adapted and perhaps even improved at some future date. Although Soviet resource endowentis not all-encomPassing and al- though Soviet technives of production in many fields are still old-fashioned as compared with the 'West, the USSR has achieved - 2 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 ? Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 "equalitymith" and therefore technologies' independence of the West in those sectors of tbe economy which it considers of vital importance: military output and much of heavy industry. Externally the burgeoning of Soviet economic power has been manifest, in a volume of international trade which has grown more rapidly than either Soviet production or total world trade. Al- though still of minor significance in the total of the world economy, Soviet exports have increased from three percent to five percent of the total of 'world exports between 1950 and 1960. Soviet commodity trade has expanded at an average annual rate of about 11 percent since 1955, a pace more rapid than*of GNP reed-about-etamel?bilthe growth of iniustrial production. Meanwhile, the nem, aggressive content of Soviet foreign economic policy was reflected in the increasing relative immortance of Soviet trade with tbe Free World in the total of 3oviet International trade. During the first half of tbe 1950's ransaction8 with other countries of tits Commaistlace accounted for 80 percent of total Soviet commodity trade, exchanges eith the Free World accounting for about one-fifth. Between 1955 and 196C4 houever, because trade eithWeetern countries grew more .eapidly than trade with other Bloc members, the share of the Free World rose from 20 to 30 percent, and in 1961 even reached ane- bird of total trade. Thus, between 1955 and 1961, while total - 3 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 trade was groving at about 11 percent a year, trade with the mmunist Moe rose by only 7 percent, but trade with the Free World expanded at an annual rate of 20 percent. This westward shift in the orientation of Soviet international exchange was a measure both of the success of its new foreign economic policy and of the importance of imports from the West to the pre- vailing Soviet economic plan (2959-1965). rihble 1 Distribution of Soviet Foreign Trade 1950, 1955, and 1961 Millions US Dollars and Percent of Total _ Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent as" I319. 100 6,487 100 11,?Aa 100 IKPTI, AVM Oloc gat 81 2d107. 72. L.n. 66 European Satellites 1,866 57 3,455 53 6,486 55 Communist China 576 18 1,392 22 918 8 Asian ? Satellites 195 6 261 4 374 3 free World 414 1.r.,&. 21li.J.921 )1n2ustria1 Vest n a n a 974 15 2,152 18 Arilderdeve. loped Countries na na 354 5 1,769 15 Unaccounted for na na 51 1 130. 1 ?17?lieeluse of rounding, may not add to the totals shown. Approved For Release 2000/04/1&:4C4A-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 _Trade as en Ideolmkeelliese_pe A. ag95.144e_bendation Before World War II Soviet international economic relations vere almost exclusively determined by their ability to. contribute to Soviet industrial strength; the manner in'whiCh their foreign economle relations were conducted vas determined by the Soviet desire for international respectability. Indeed the single compelling goal of all of Soviet policy vas the at- tainment of industrial power at the most rapid rate consistent with domestic security. Exports represented diversion of resources from domestic use which was suffered only because the resources could be exchange for commodities 'Whose contribution to Industrial growth would be even greeter -- modern machinery. At the wame time the Soviet leaders, smarting from their treat- ment as internatIonal outlays by the Western powers, strove so to eomPort themselves in international transactions as to prove their respectability. %he Soviet Union yes scrupulous in meeting all of its commitments on time and at par. Xt purchased almost entirely for cash, exporting gold to meet its debts yhen its export receipts were insufficient. When legal disputes arose over international commerce, soviet courts strove for complete Objectivity in their treatment of for end in the nature of their decisions. By 1940 as a result of Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 diligent and unscrupulous measures to mdbilize domestic resources, the USSR had achieved an impressive measure of industrial strength. And through diligent and scrupulous cultivation of its international commercial reputation, it succeeded in attaining a position of commercial respectdbility and in fashioning for itself a small niche in world trade. During these formative years, exclusive concentration on overcoming its economic weakness inhibited the Soviet leader- ship from developing a more aggressive foreign economic policy. Certain hesitating steps along the path of economic diplomacy vete attempted but not pursued. The fact that traditional Russian interest in the Middle East, for example, was sustained by the Communist regime was illuetrated by offers of econemic aid to Afghanistan, Turkey and Persia in the early 1920s. In- deed the stripling Soviet economy constructed several textile plants on. the basis of long-term credits, and provided technical aid to these countries, but such activities were necessarily limited by its own compelling domestic requirements. The full development of trade as an ideological weapom awaited the growth of Soviet ecoromic power. When, after World War IX, through the use of subversion and armed forte the USSR succwIded in creating an empire of Satellite states in Eastern 6 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Eerops? it was for tbe first time in a position of influence in an intezeationalsorket. The Soviet Union was therefore able to uee comoditerezobange as the chief means of consolidating and extending its position of power in Eastern Europe. The creation of a Ccumunist state in Mainland China in 1949 further extended the scope of the internationalenrket organized on the basis of Soviet institutions. Because the USSR vas the largest trading partner in this "Socialist vorld market," its transactions could not but influence the market. 'Even this extension of its international eoonomic rela- tions to enconpass other Socialist partners, hovever, brought little chanpinbasic Soviet foreign economic policy. Tbe role of international trade with socialist and capitalist wearies alike remained essentially growth-oriented, valued for its con- tribution to the modernization and expansion of Soviet industry. Between 1948 and 1955 a variety of devices enabled tbe USSR, both to extract a sizable imeort surplus in its trade with the European Satellites and to effect a complete reorientation of the international commerce -of these countries, away fran roamer tradirg partners in Western Europe toward the Soviet Union and other. Communist states. Through reparation deliveries and war booty the USSR acquired machinery and egpipment estimated to have amounted to upward Of 10 billion dollars? Pseudo-legal - 7 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : C1A-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 ' Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 techniqees fUrther enataed the USSR to arrange a redistribution of former German assets in Eastern Europe in such a way that it acquired a claim to as rmzch as one-half of the current produc- tion of certain Satellite countries. By placing orders for equipment and materials in Easternikumpo the USSR was able to direct the course of industrial investment and thus the structure of industryin these countries to its own requirements. The Soviet Union became the main supplier of raw materials to Satellite industry and the prime market for their finished pro- duct. 2%* Ubiquitous presence of Soviet advisers threughout Eastern Europe at all levels of government and industry insured the efficacy of Soviet control. The development of economic relations with Mainland China after the assumption of control by the Cemmunist regime in 1949 folloved quite a different path. The Chinese Ccumunist party attained control over the Mainland 'without aid from the Soviet 'Gaon. From the outset economic relations between the USSR and ceumnniet China were governed by a policy of mutual accommodation. Chinese agricultural products and raw materials were exehanged for Soviet industrial goods; the Soviet Union provided several long-term credits for purposes-Of imbestrial development and the services of scientists, technicians, and specialists of various kinds to advise the Chinese in their economic development. - 8 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 From the Soviet viewpoint the expansion of trade with China provided an efficient and economic contribution to the economic development of the Soviet Far East. B. Fashioning the Weapon The ehift to an aggressive foreign economic policy in the 1950's appeared to be abrupt, but actually was thoroughly conceived, baying lomg been part of Communist strategy. Tbe conceptual scheme of Lenin concerning the historically necessary course of political development, while ordaining that Capitalism ultimatelyggve way to Communism, insisted that the 'underdeveloped countries need not In every case pass through the stage of Capitalism in progressing toward Socialimn. And since the 1920s Soviet writers have looked forward to the day when the USSR would be in a position materially to aid these countries along the direct route to Communism. By tbe mid-1950's the Soviet leader- sbip apparently felt that internal economic growth had so diminished the country's vulnerability that it was finally in a position to inaugurate an aggressive program of economic diplomacy. Offers of foreign aid "without strings" to underde- veloped countries began to multiply in 1954 and 1955, and although a few minor credits were extended in these pare, the Soviet aid offensive was on the whole skeptically received. The conclusion of a major military aid agreement with Eglypt in late - 9 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 1955#* and the prompt delivery of the equipment and technical personnel contracted for, gave the program its first real nomentum. in the second half of the decade under the leadership of the USSR , credits and grants were exteaamihy other members of the Communist Bloc to underdeveloped countries for military and developmental purposes in increasing volume. In the military sphere, the form of Soviet aid varied from the training of officers in Staff Colleges of the USSR to the provision of modern jet fighters. Economic aid has similarly comprised a great variety of industries, ranging from a modern integrated steel mill to geologic surveys and small workshops. Trade agreements were signed providing for an exchange of the major exports of these countries against machinery, materials and technical advice from the USSR and Eastern Europe and cultural and technical delegations moved to and from the Bloc in growing magnitude. By 1961 the USSR had achieved a secure position of influence in the economies of Egypt, India, Afghanistan, Indonesia and Cuba and had established the basis for expanding relations with a large number of other countrtes. At the same time Soviet offers of scholarships for academic and technical training in the USSR provided an increasing flow of students and trainees from most of the underdeveloped countries of Asia., Africa and Latin America. 4----KIWarrire1oc signatory partner was Czechoslovakia, the materiel provided was primari34. Soviet. 10 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 The shift from a defensive foreign economic policy was also evident in Soviet relations with the European Satellites. An contrast to the early post-ear period when the Satellites Imre forced to contribute heavily to Soviet economic recon- struction, in the late 1950's the Soviet Union provided sizeable quantities of bath emergency and developmental aid to other ecumenist countries. The policy shift frem the stick to the carrot inSoviet treatment -of Eastern Enrope vas partially the result of the 1956 Satellite revolts; at the same time, however, the relative affluence of the Soviet Unien made the policy shift possible. Since 1954 Soviet economic aid to underdeveloped Free World countries has amounted to about $3.5 billion, or about 70 percent of the total aid program of the Sino-Soviet Bloc. Duriag the same period, the USSR gave near4 $4 billion of elk also in the form of credits and grants, to other Communist countries. While during the past two years new aid extensions to underdeveloped countriea have slowed considerably, the opposite has been true of aid for the Bloc. In these years credits and grants for East Germany and the Communist Far East were probably at an all time high. Soviet adventures in international finance have not been confined to the developeent of their foreign ai& program, for in recent years the USSR has been active not only as a Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 lender of long and medium term capital, but also as a borrower. Tn contrast with its earlier history vhen Soviet trade with Western countries was conducted almost exclusively on a cash basis since the initiation of the current seven year plan (1959-65) Soviet purchasing missions in Western Europe, Japan and the US have bargained as vigorously over the terms of the sale as over the price of the plant and machinery for which they mere negotiating. With heightening ccmpetition among the engineering industries of the industrialized ccuntries of the Free World, the difference between 'winning or losing a sizeable contract bas often been determined on the basis of such financial terms. Tbe USSR has consequently been able to finance a signi- ficant portion of Soviet imports from these countries since 1.960 on tbe basis of 5 and even 7 year credits. By the end of 1962 net Soviet indebtedness to the Industrial West for such credit financing eill probillaybe about half a billion dollars. Deliveries of aid goods tend to lag behind the aid commitment. Soviet goods and services delivered to underde- velopmi countries amount to about one-quarter of aid commitments, or to less than one billion dollars tor.the entire period sine* 1954. Considering the aggregate of Soviet borrowing and lending activities with non-Communist countries for the same period, the 1SSR has delivered unrequited exports to the underdeveloped West 3.2 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 and has reoeivedunxequited imports from the inftstrial West. On balance net Soviet international captbasalvements with non-Communist countries have represented a net outflow of Soviet spoils and services to the West of only about one-quarter of a billion dollars. Perhaps the most dramatic use of international trade as a weapon of foreign policy occurred in mid-1960 in the course of the Sino-Soviet ideological dispute. At that time the Soviet Union precipitously withdrem most if not all of its technicians, numbering upmard of 30000, who were working in China to aid in Chinese industrialization. This act of eeonomio warfare was followed by a veritable collapse in Sino-Soviat trade which by the end of 1961 had dropped to two-fifths of its 1959 level.. Thus, in leas than a decade Soviet international economic activities have ceased to be of a cautious, conserva- tive nature and have rather become adventurous and at times even flaeboyant. That these new policies have been successfa 13 attested by the position of economic and political influence that the usan has achieved in tbe international arena. Although Soviet international trade accounts for only a barely signifi- mut portion of total world, trade, its ability to influence the AUSirgil riiiiabIe decline in Sino-Soviet exchange would have occurred in any event because of the serious economic difficulties in China, the unilateral withdrawal of Soviet technicians by itself fostered mistrust and caused a diversion of China's trade away from the USSR. -13- Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 ? Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 economies of certain countries and the behavior of Certain commalttymmatets has been impressively demonstrated. III. Trade with the Communist Bloc A. The Institutions of the Socialist World Market 1. Insulation of the Domestic BcomomE In a completely controlled econagy in which pro- duction and consumption are planned at a level arid of a composi- tion to insure a very rapid rate of industrial growth, the prime function of foreign trade is to provide the commodities necesmary to plan fulfillment mbiah are not available fran domestic sources? At the same time, because 8W:4W:to/and predictabilitoraxe necesseTy to successful planning, as well aa to plan fUlfillment, the foreign trade mechanism must operate in sueh a fashion as to protect the domestic economy train disturbing foreign Influence. The internal price systme of a Communist country is so devised as to encourage the use of some ccommaties and discourage the use of others; in order to function successfully in the light of Communist goals, it must be insulatet and isolated from foreign influences. For example, in order to restrict the demand fat consumer goods in Bloc countries, relatively high prices axe set for such commodities. In a free economy, high prices would direct a major part of omnuodity imports to the consumer sector, a development which would thwart Bloc military Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 ? Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 and industrial growth imperatives. Strict controls over foreign trade, accordingly, are necessary in a Communist country, Writers in the Communist Bloc have long pointed with pride to the fact that their economies are protected from the volatile and erratic price movements that characterize Western markets. Insofar as their pride is justified, it is equally true that the internal price systems of Bloc countries bear no relation to one another, for the barricades which pro- tect the domestic systems from influences from the Capitalist world also operate to insulate them from develop:eras within the Bloc. This isolation or the internal price systems of Bloc countries has been achieved by an of rigid state con- trols over all international transactions. Foreign trade is a mcelopoly of the state and with other Bloc countries is subject to rigid, bilateral balancing; with few exceptions, no oashmoves, all transactions being settled by the movement of goods, Inter- national purchases and sales are conducted in prices and denominated in currencies which are different from those pre- vailing internally. The separation of the two price systems has been achieved and maintained by an elaborate systaa of artificial exchange rates and budgetary supports. As a result Bloc ourrencies are purely national currencies with no international - 15 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 uses. The zloty is usable only within Poland, the forint only within Hungary and the Soviet ruble only within the USSR. Eco- nomic intercourse between a Cammunist country and a country of ? the Free World is negotiated in a Western monetary unit. Bi- lateral paynents accounts are also maintained in a Western monetanrumit and balances are settled in Western exchange. Trade among members of the Communist Bloc themselves, however, are con- ducted in terms of an accounting unit termed a ruble. 2. Ruble --Paces The ruble used in intra-Bloc commodity transac- tions, which can be termed the foreign exchange ruble or the devisa ruble: is purely an accounting unit. It is not repre- sented. by any certificate or piece of metal or paper as is the internal ruble. The devise ruble is solely a conceptual standard for measuring value and need have no_more relation to the internal ruble than the quart which is the unit of liquid measure hen to the quart which is the unit of dry measure. As long as Bloc foreign trade prices axe different frun Soviet internal prices for the same commodity, the value of the foreign exchange ruble is different from the value of tbe Soviet rale. a. Nature of Bloc .TradePrici31 Practice Trade agreements, or protocols to existing agreements, are negotiated among countries of the Bloc annually. - 16 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 'Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 These agreements simply list the commodities to be exchanged and the total value of trade to be achieved. It is left to trade delegations to decide in conference the details of price and quantity fox each specific commodity to be exported or importel. These? meetings are marked by strenuous bargaining and vigorous competition between the negotiatirq partners. The exporters of commodities for which the demand is strong -- for example, most Czechoslovak machinery, Polish coal, Rumanian oil and timber, and Soviet industrial goods and materials -- can command not only good prices but also "hard" commodities in exchange. In fact, because of the pervasiveness of shortages throughout the Moe, a strong bargaining position is used more often to acquire scarce commodities than to achieve a more favorable price. The negotiating partners go to these meting armed with documentation about world market prices. This in- volves information about prices at which the ccumodity in question bas actuall,y been sold recently in specific transactions in the West. In fact, in the Ministry of Foreign Trade of most Bloc countries, there is a division which does nothing except collect such price information. Thus worlAi market prices do form the basis for Bloc foreiga trade prices. These prices (the dollar price multiplied by the official exchange rate of the ruble for the dollar) are the point at which bargaining begins. Strictly, - 17 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 however, there is no such thing as a single woad market price. The price at ehich the UK buys baoaa frau Danmark for example, maybe quite different frmn the price it pays for bacon fran New Zealand or Argentina. Thus the Bloc exporter can always find a relatively high Western price-to support his claim, but the importer can also document from Free World sources his claim to a lower price. The price finalky agreed on depends on the relative bargaining strength of the two countries as colored by their needs and avallabilities. Once the price has been agreed on, it remains in force for the entire year, and often for several years. It not intrequently happens, however, that no aweement on prices can be reached. Then trade continues, being recorded at last year's prices, subject to final adjustment when agreement is at length reached. In fact it appears that the difficulties atten- dant on reaching agreement on price have been as important as the necessity of stability and predictability for planning purposes in keep:Wage-ices constant over several years. b. Historical Course of Bloc Trade Prices Although Bloc trade prices have been determined at. bargaining sessions since the end of World War XI, the relative strength of the bargaining partners has changed0 immediately aXter the war the USSR announced that commodities would be Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 exchmwdvithin the Bloc at world. market prices. At this time, Satellite trade representatives: who had no way of knowing what these prices were, could only take tbe word of the Soviet representatives. They began to realivs, however, that the prices of Soviet exports were very high and that the prices of their own exports, were law. They themselves undertook some market research and thereafter vent to the negotiations possessed of documentation. In this way tbe Satellites praetayteNe gradually forced Bloc trade prices to their 'world market levels. There is some evidence to indicate that in the late 1940's most Bloc trade prices were consideralayabove vorld market ;elms) with Soviet export prices being higher than Soviet import prices. Since then, Bloc trade prices seem on the average .to have declined. 3. DLE)....e_Rate, Xn March 1950 by an appropriate definition of its gold content, the USSR set the rate at which the rale was to be measured against other currencies at the equivalent of $0.25, and maintained this official exchange rate until 1 January 1961, At this rate the ruble vas considerataymervalued in the sense that 25 in tbe US would buy much mere than mou34 one ruble in the MM. A rate which overstated the value of the ruble use prObably choaen for purposes of prestige. That the rate was purely arbitrary had no significance to the trolinglartmers of the USSR, however, for those in the Free World never had occasion -19- Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 to use it,* and those in the Bloc used it only for accounting purposes. Other Communist countries simi1ar1y determined at an arbitrary level the rates at vbich their currencies were to be measured against the dollar and the ruble. Table 2 Foreign Exchange Rates for Commercial fteansactions for Currencies of the Soviet Bloc 1954-60 and 1961-62 County , Hate of Exchange 3p54-do 3961-62 Unit of In terms of In terms of In terms of Inter= of Currency USS1 _ US$1 US$1 US$1 Albanta Lek 50.0 12.5 50.0 55.56 Bulgaria ley 6.8 1.7 1.17 2/ 1.3 9./ Czechoslova- kia Crown 7.2 1.8 7.2 8.o East Germany Ostmark 2.2 0.5 2.22 yi 2.47 13j( Hungary Forint 11.7 2.9 11.74 13.04 Poland Zloty 4.0 1.0 4.0 4.44 Rumania tau 6.0 1.5 6 6.67 USSR Ruble 4.o 0.9 --a.evnuar9y61. Official rates diving 196i: 6.8 lave per Us$1, 7.56 leva per 1 ruble. , b. Altbmigithis is the official rate, (to rates in use since 1959 are as follows: 4.2 ME per US$1; 4.67 ENE per 1 ruble. * --EireaCiBiriat case of non-conortodity transactions is discussed below. 20 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 'Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Because these official exchange rates were set with the intention-of insulating the internal economy from extermal influences with no regard to relative price levels, the conversion of export receipts or import payments into the domestic currency, an adjustment necessary for maintaining domestic accounts, resulted in fOreign trade prices ehich bore no relation to domestie prices. In general internal Bloc prices when convertel at official rates were higher -- but higher by varying degrees -- than Western wices. Consequently, the domestic equivalent of export receipts was in most cases considerably below the internal price of the ctsumodity, and the opposite vas true of import payments.' These price differentials thus resulted in price losses an exports awl profits on imports which were absorbed by the country's budget. Because of the existence of these price differentials, and especially the negative differential characteristic of exports, Bloc exports have been termed "subsidized." This is a very special type of subsidy', however, and results solely froe the exists*** of an arbitrarily high foreign exchange rate. Moreover, exports to other Bloc countries as well as exports to the West would be "subsidized" by Communiet countries in this sense, and necessarily so as long as Bloc foreigo trade prices remained loiter then inter- nal prices of member countries. The only Bloc exports 'which would not be subsidized becauee of the artificially high exchange rate vould be exports -21- Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 of those commodities Whose internal price in the exporting country vas equal to or lower than the export price converted into the domestie eurreney at official rates. Thus if the Iegel price of some raw material within the USSR were 130 rubles per ton and if this commodityware exported by the USSR at $20, or 80 rUbles, per ton a price loss o' 20 rubles would be involved. 2his pride loss is directly attributable to the use of a 250 ruble exchange rate wizen the implicit exdhange rats appropriate for this commodity is at the level of 5 rubles to the dollar, or 200. Whether the total of price differential losses borne by the budget is greater or less than the total of profits depends on the structure of the internal price system of the Communist couehry as well as on the level of the exchange rates If the isolated internal price system is such that, at the official exchange rate, the purchasing power of the currency is over- valued, but considerably more overvalued in regard to some goods than others, then, the structure of the internal price system, as uell se its level, is distorted from that of the world market. Under such conditions -- mhidh seem to Characterise the internal price systems of Communist countries a change in the exchange rate by itself could decrease the gross price differential loss and profit, but would not eliminate a net profit or loss. A realistic exdhange rates would be one - 22 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 representing the average relationship between internal ruble prices and world prices in dollara or sterlinig for goods entering inter- national trade. Given a distorted internal price structure, how- ever, the variation of individual ruble-dollar price relationships around tbe average would be large and pradbly skewed., resulting in sone net price differential for the sum of price losses and profits on trade. The 1961 revision of the official exchange rate of the ruble, which was ostensibly an appreication of the ruble in terms of Western currencies, vas probdbly undertaken for the pur- pose of reduoing the gross price differential profit and loss to be borne by the Soviet budget on account of foreign trade. By redefining the gold content of the ruble, its relationship to the dollar was changed from the equivalent of 250 to $1.11, or from 4 rubles to .9 rubles to the dollar. Ostensibly the value of the rnble was raised by 4.4 times. Since the USSR revised its interrial price level simultaneously, however, by dividing all prices by 10, the exchange rate of the ruble as a measure or relative purchasing power was in fact depreciated. The new exchange rate, however, apeears to be more realistic as a measure of relative price levels. While considerations of prestige mere prObably not absent in setting the value of tbe rtible higher than the dollar, the degree of overvaluation has certwinl5r been considemftblyreduced if not wholly eliminated. -23- Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 In setting the foreign exchange rate or the rUble at a more realistic level, the amount of price differential pro.. fits collected on imports by the budget, and price differential losses paid 'by the budget on exports, would be considerably reduced. In fact, at the new exchange rate differences between internal and external prices will reflect almost exclusively distortions in the Soviet price structure. Soviet planners are therefore in a position to note the commodity composition of their foreign trade which involves the most extreme price differentials and to examine the reasons for these differentials in the interests of economic efficiency and maximum productivity. Although in the past Soviet planners have been little concerned with relative costs in determining the composition of their foreign trade, pressure on growth rates vill increasingly lead toward ration- alisation, of sectors of their economy. 4. Non-Commercial Teansactions Before 1957 the countries of the Communist Bloc maintained a single schedule of exchange rets, the rates being all consistent with one another and with the rate of 4 rubles to the dollar. The rates were applicable to both commercial and so-ealled noncommercial transactions. The distinction between these two rests on the difference between transactions involving Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 commodities and services exchanged with someone outside the country and transactions involving goods and services sold to and consumed by a foreigner within the ccuntry's borders. Commercial transactions include the international purchases and sales nf commodities and commodity transport. Boncemmercial transaetions inolude receipts and expenditures by international tourists and by embassies, receipts and expenditures for passenger transportation and international telephone and telegraph services, and individual and institutional remittances. Because Bloc credit transactions -- borrowing and 'ending -- relate to goods and are directly effected. in goods, commercial exchange rates apply both to the receipt of the credit and to the payment of interest and principal.* Deginning in early 1957 Bloc members individually announced new official exchange rates for noncommercial transac- tions. In most cases, these new rates represented a depreciation of the Bloc currency in terms of Western currencies (for example, Western tourists were able to buy Soviet rubles at the rate of 10 to US $1 compared with only 4 to 03 $1 before 1957) and, except for Poland, an appreciation of Satellite currencies in terms of the Soviet rale. Same Satellite currencies were appreciated, others depreciated, in terms of other Satellite currencies. The reason for the new rates for noncommercial pur- poses in relation to the West seemed to lie in an attempt on the 4---Tiloc credit transactions almost always are credits to finance the exports of the lending country. The commodities involved are usually valued at the prices prevailing in the trade agreement be- tween the two countries concerned. Similarly, repayments are effected in goods at the prices of the current trade agreement. Approved For Release 2000/04/18-: a8A-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 part of all Bloc members to increase earnings of Western currencies by encouraging tourists from the West. The new rates in relation to other Bloc countries seemed to represent an attempt to make Intra-Bloc settlements of noncommercial accounts more equitable by relating the cost of currencies to their various purchasing powers. Whereas Bloc commercial exchange rates were all Internally connistent with one another and with Free World currencies, these new noncommercial rates in themselves involved each Bloc member in a system of dual rates. The noncommercial exchange rates proclaimed by any one country represented one internally consistent set in relation to all Free World countries and a second internally consistent set for all Bloc countries, but between the Bloc and the West they were not consistent. For example, the Polish zloty exchanged at a rate of 24 to US $1 for these purposes and the Soviet ruble at a rate of 10 to US $1, but the noncommercial rate between Poland and the USSR was set at 1.5 zioties to the ruble rather than 2.4 zloties which would be consistent with the dollar rates. These discrepancies could be maintained only because of strict controls over the uses of domestic currencies by all Bloc members. All transactions among Bloc countries are finally settled in goods. When, for example, Soviet specialists or technicians are sent to a Satellite country, the latter spays the 26 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 USSR for their services eventually by exporting commodities to the USSR. Each Bloc country maintains with every other member a noncommercial account through *ahich the value of these non- commodity transactions is recorded. At the end of each year these accounts are balanced against one another, the net debit or credit being transferred to the commodity account for settle- ment. Because of their nature noncommercial transactions Involve purchases and sales at derestip prices rather than at foreign trade prices and because the internal price levels of individual Bloc members are not only unrelated to one another but vary considerably, the previous system of clearing noncommercial balances at commercial exchange rates put at a disadvantage those countries whose currencies were least overvalued or uhose-inter- nell prices were relatively low. Since the Soviet ruble was appreciated in term of only 1 Satellite currency but depreciated in terms of 5, it seems likely that the net effect on Intra-Sloc commodity flows of the the noncommercial exchange rate revisions mould have been a reduction in Soviet purchasing power in the Satellites. In 1961 after the revision of the Soviet official egcbange rate, the distinction between a commercial and non- commercial rate for transactions vith Western countries was e11m4nated, the new rate applying to tourist and embassy Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 ApprareigesAFIRAULORS1/e/F ,?.il-n?lOaTalig3190A0lee62191.06A021-1 schedule of noncommercial rates vis..a..vis other Bloc countries vas retained? however, the only change being the appreciation of the ruble by 10 times to reflect the change in internal. Soviet prices. Table 3 Foreii Exchange Rate for Non-Comercial Transactions for Currencies of the Soviet Bloc count Unit of Currency Rate of change - In terms of USS1 In terms of 3. Ruble a! Albania Lek 150W 100W Bulgaria Lev 1.17 0.89 gf Czechoslovakia Crown 14.34 ly 11.6 2/ East Germany Ostm9.rk 4.2 Eti 3.9 pi Hungary Forint 23.48 RV 14.0 g/ Poland Zloty 214.00 d 15.0 2/ Rumania Let' 15.00 14/ 9.7 W USSR Ruble 0.9 2/ a. anuary e r ex or 0330 rates. b. As of 3. July 1957. c. As of 3. January 1961. a. As of 1 January 3962. e. As of 1 January 3958. f. As of 1 April 1957. g. As of 11 Feburary 3957. h. As of 13. May 3960. se The 3957 adjustment of intra-Bloc noncommerc.ial rates represented the first step taken by Sloe countries to relate exchange rates of relative purchasing powers. As such it also represented a retreat from the philosophy of "insulation and isola- tion 0 and from the concept of an absolute internal economy unrelated Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 to that of the outside world. The 1961 revision of the basic commercial rate of the ruble in terms of Western currencies was the second step in the same direction. At the least these moves are evidence of a recognition of the impossibility of absolute insulation without complete cessation of all economic intercourse. Settlement of noncommercial transactions on an equitable basis requires the use of an exchange rate which reflects relative pur- chasing power. A meaningful exchange rate can serve many other useful purposes, however, and is essential for determining the relative merit of an expansion of domestic output as opposed to an increase in imports of a given good. An economy committed to high growth rates must be Increasingly concerned with all aspects of economic efficiency, including the efficiency of its foreign trade operation. B. Trade with Eastern Europe:_ from the Stick to the Carrot 1. The Period of ,the Stick In tbe early post-war period Soviet foreign economic policy vas dominated by two related goals: the rapid restoration of domestic economic strength and the creation in Eastern Europe of a Soviet-controlled buffer area to protect the exposed frontier. The immediate post-war years were a period of plunder, the USSR 1.ak1,ng as the victor's spoils in former enemy countries productive equipment of all kinds, dismantling factories, transport facilities, and worshops for transfer to the Soviet Union. In addition to such -29- Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 war booty, the USSR took as reparations title to much German property located in Hungary, Rumania and Bulgaria, thereby obtaining control over several hundred producing Amterprises. These former German assets provided the basis for the Soviet- Satellite joint-stock companies, formed in 1946-1948, through 'which the USSR acquired control over a major share of Satellite mining, manufacturing, transportation and finance. Reparations deliveries from the current output of these and other plants were important not only to the restoration of the Soviet economy but provided the mechanism for Obtaining a high degree of con- trol over economic activity in Eastern Europe. East German reparation deliveries during 1945-50, for example9 amounted to about $9 billion 'while commercial exports to the USSR aggregeted only $5.5 billion. After the initial period of plunder when Soviet exploitation of resources and capital assets had threatened to destroy the economic foundations of Eastern Europe, the pattern of Soviet treatment shifted to one more consistent with its long-run goal of consolidating its domination of the area. Through reparation deliveries and export orders, Communist party pressures and the presence of Soviet advisors in key ministerial and production posts, Satellite trade vas redirected from its traditional Western orientation into Soviet Bloc channels. -30- Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 'Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Satellite economies were developed in such a 'way as to make them dependent On the Soviet Union for markets and raw materials. Priority development of heavy industry and neglect of traditional agricultural consumer goods production narrowed the basis for Satellite trade with the West. The economic reorientation of Eastern Europe was formalized by the formation in 1.919 of the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (CEMA) to coordinate ia- ternal ecommic plans and foreign economic relations of the Soviet Bloc. Th e shift in the pattern of trade and production of Eastern Europe subjected the Satellite economies to severe strains. In addition Soviet exploitative policies and autarkic development plans overtaxed the productive resources of the area and caused much resentment against local governments as well as against the USSR. In 1953 the new Kremlin leadership, recognizing that the stability of the area was threatened, began to relax the more burdensome controls and lighten its iron demands Soviet'advisere wore withdrawn, discrimieatory pricing practices were revised and the dissolution of the joint stock companies was initiated. The Soviet leadership also urged some modifications in Satellite economic plans to provide some concessions to consumer demand. The adjustments made in Soviet-Sateilite relations were not adequate, however, to reverse the growing disproportion between the industrial capacity being creatyl in Eastern Europe - 31 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 aM the raw materials, befell and power resources necessary to support it. The Soviet Uhion thus either had to divert increasing quantities of its own raw material resources to bolster the lagging Satellite economies or risk &Itellite economic reorientation toward tbe West. The Soviet Union chose to do neither, and-as a result, tbe initial measures taken were wholly inadequate to avert the further deterioration in the economies of the Satellites which contrfbuted directly to the Polish and Hungarian upheavals in the fall of 1956. 2. The Period of the Crrrot Following the 1956 uprisings the USSR sought to restore political and economic stability to the Satellites by offeriag major economic concessions and by removing the more blatant inequities in Soviet economic dealings with several of the Satellites. Concessions included debt cancellations, eliminating discriminatory pricing practices, and the like. Weet important, the Soviet Union agreed to assist the Satellites In overcoming dislocatione caused by the Polish and Hungarian events and generally to assist their economic recovery. Thus, the Soviet Union extended large emergency credits in the form or commodity deliveries and foreign exchange (see discussion on credits below). It also negotiate& supplementary-trade agreements notably with Bast Germany and Bulgaria, aseuring those countries -32- Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 of additional markets for the products of depressed industries and guaranteeing them additional supplies of industrial raw materials and foodstuffs generally in short supply. Following the attainment of relative economic stability in the Satellites, the USSR in 1957 and 1958 renewed its efforts to achieve economic coordination in Eastern Europe. New long-term economic plans of the Satellites for the period 1961-65 were to be dovetailed with the new Soviet seven-year plan (1959-1965). Economic coordination was to be effected on a sector-by-sector basis, with priority going to the development, on a national or regional scale as appropriate, of an adequate raw material base for the Soriet Bloc as a whole. In support of the economic coordination program, the Soviet Uhion negotiated five-year (1961-65) trade agreements with each of the Satellites, in which it undertook to be the principal supplier of Satellite Import requirements for industrial raw materials, fuels, and foodstuffs, and the principal export market for Satellite manufactures. The USSR has since made continued efforts to strengthen the Satellite economies within the framework of the CEMA integration program, increasing supplies of raw materials, furnishing economic development loans and emergency credits where needed, encouraging joint Satellite investment projects, etc. -33- Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 " Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 That the Soviet leadership is nom far from satisfied with the progress of the Satellite economies and the integration program is evident in the decision in June 1962 to create a new Executive Directorate to oversee CBMA and the appointment to that body on a full-time basis of the men who have been the chief economic planners of the USSR and some of the Satellites. Indeed, the appointment of top-level planners would appear to indicate that a major effort will be made to correct the "unproductive expendi- tures a material resources fiiht2h7be1d back . . . growth . to assist the limping agricultural economies of the European Bloc, and to strengthen the Soviet Bloc economy in general. Given Khrusbebev's self-imposed economic compeiltica between East and West, the task of making the CE MA economic grouping more viable becomes even more urgent in the face of the rapid strides .being made by the European Common Market: . 3. Economic Assistance Varying use of the carrot and stick by the USSR with respect to its European Satellites is perhaps bast exemplified by its economic assistance policy (or lack thereof). During the first decade following World War II when unrequited Soviet imports (reparations payments, mar booty, profits fres Soviet-Satellite joint-stock companies, etc.) could be counted in the tens of billions of dollars, the USSR sporadically extended credits to the Satellites as an ad hoc response to particular situations. Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 ' Approved For Release 2000/04/18: CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 TI e bulk of the economic assistance extended by the Soviet Union during the period 1945-1955, which amounted to about $1.5 billion, consisted of credits to Boland and East Germany, in the latter case, apparently in response to the unrest in East Germany in 1953. During the year of the revolts and in the succeed- ing years, (1956-57) the USSR provided economic aid to the Satellites amounting to about $1.2 billion,* or almost as nuch as that provided in the previous decade. In addition, the USSR wrote off Table 4 Soviet Economic Credits and. Grant3 Extended to the EUropean Satellites 1945-1962 Million US$ Country 1945-55 1956 1957 1958 1959 1966 1961 1962 Total Albania 166 48 93 247 Bags:eta 198 92 72 44 162 568 Czecboslovskia 48 14 62 East Germany 363 20 260 235 475 ."/ 1,353 MIngarY 43 41 262 35 381 Poland, 614 300 914 Aumanla .94 95 ? ......... 4.1????ma 4?.? 189 olloarmwo 1,466 548 656 314 93 162 475 fl./ 3,714 a. Theexter?WariaRiThi?t?ditoermaninThir-ry?W-v-al-uid at $310 million. It is believed that this was part of the $475 million credit extended in 1961. 7?17 Excluding Soviet credits for the purchase of Soviet holdings in joint-stock companies. Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : 9,A;RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 *Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 various debts for Soviet aid extended before 1956 and for the repurchase of Soviet shares in the joint Soviet-Satellite companies estimated at a value of $1 billion. Also, the Soviet Union agreed to renegotiate to the advantage of the Satellites previous agree- ments concerning prices for "commercial and noncommercial services," costs of Soviet troop maintenance, and certain transfers of Soviet property. The estimated value of these additional concessions was almost $1 billion. Other benefits which have accrued to the Satellites since 1956 include more favorable loan repayment terms. The 1956-57 period thus represented the pinnacle of Soviet largesse with respect to Eastern Europe, and it was essentially a rescue operation. Nevertheless) despite the decline In credits to the European Satellites since that time, these years marked the end of gross Soviet exploitation of the area and the beginning of Soviet recognition that its awn self-interest lay in the economic well-being of the Soviet Bloc as a whole. With the exceptian of aid to East Oereanr, practically all Soviet economic assistance to the Bloc since this period has been in the form of economic development credits to the lesser developed countries. 4. Trade Spurred by the "closed Bloc" policy of Stalin, Soviet trade with the European Satellites increased rapti4 in - 36 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 *Ap 11?4 111 carA91012001-1 3946 or less than one-third of total Soviet trade to more than $3 billion in 1953 or more than half of total Soviet trade of 0,700 million. More importantly, the orientation of the Satellite countries' trade shifted radically toward the USSR. Ay 3953, the share of the USSR, ranged from one-third of the foreign trade of Hungary and Roland to nearly three-fifths of Bulgarian and Albanian trade (see Table 6). The failure of the Soviet Union to provide anon:rending market for SatallitorOnvorts or a reliable source of raw materials is reflected lathe decline of the Ahem of the USSR in the Satellites' trade between 1953 and 2955. Since then, however, Soviet-Satellite trade has undergone a substantial increase, averaging more than 11 percent annual/y through 1.961 When it reached $6.5 billion (see Table 5). The growth of Soviet-Satellite trade has been particularly-rapid since the, beginning of the Soviet Seven-Tear Plan Period (1.959- /965), and is expected to be maintained throughout the period, engendering an, even greater dependence of the Satellites on the USSR. Table 5 Soviet 7rade with the European Satellites 1955451 122/ 12g 122/ Exports 1,792 1,763 2,550 Imports 1,663 1,815 1,915 Teta/2/ 3,455 3,583 10465 at 1222. 2,320 2,950 2,206 2,539 4,526 5,470 12--13-131-22.--VE 19601961. 3,118 3,420 2,839 3,066 5,937 6,1186 a. Because of rounding, omponents may not add to the totals shown. Approved For Release 2000/04/1n FIR-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 'Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Table 6 SovietShare in European Satellite Trade 1953, 2955, 1960, and 1965 Percent of Total Estimated Country 2953 3Q5 202 3.965 Albania 57 ko 53 n a. Bulgaria 56 53 54 Czechoslovakia 36 34 38 East Gamow n a 38 43 45 EungarY 22 29 36 Poland 33 32 30 35 Rumania us 49 In recent years, the bulk of Soviet trade vith the Satellites bas been conducted vith the more highly Izidustrialized countries of East Germ, Czechoslovakia, and Poland; trade vith these eau:Aries accounts for more than tvo-thirds of total Soviet. Satellite trade. These three countries as veil as BUngary pro- vide the USSR vith about three-fourths of total Soviet imports of machinery and equipment. These imports supply a substantial share of total Soviet requirements for the pima goals of certain sectors, e.g., transport, matallurgys.chemicalso By the same token, theee_gre.the-vountrie's 161ch account for a large share 38 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 'Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 of the Soviet fuels and raw materials exported to the Satellites. Soviet trade with the lesser developml Satellites of Rumania and Bulgaria is of a different nature, involving generally the export of Soviet manufactured goods in -exchange for raw materials. Geperelly speaking, hovever, Soviet-Satellite trade can be re- presented as an exchange of Soviet fuels and raw materials for Satellite maehinery and equipment and finished consumer goods* C. Trade with China: From the Carrot to the Stick From the very beginning of Communist rule in China, Soviet-Chinese trade increased at a rapid pace. Throughout most of tbe decade of the 1950's China was the USSR's most important trading partner and Soviet economic policy toward China was reflected in the economic, technical, and military assistance provided to Chimmbytto USSR. The keystone of Soviet-Chinese economic relations vas in the 291 major industrial projects schedaled to be built in China through 1967 using Soviet machinery, equiluent? and technical assistance. Such Soviet support as has been provided for China's drive to became a major industrial and political power has been motivated by a desire to bolatar an alliance designed to enhance the strength and vcrld power position of the Soviet Union and the Bloc as a vhole. Thus p until recently, the economic relation- ships between the two countries could be characterised as one of - 39 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 *Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 mutual accomodation. The intruaion, however, of ideological and political differences into Sino-Soviet economic relations led to the ness withdrawal of Soviet technicians from China in mid-.1960. Tbe resulting mistreat between the two trading partners, =Whined vith rapidly 'worsening economic conditions in China and the apparent refusal of the USSR to provide mere than emodicum of ecomomic assistance, (or the refusal of China to make the ideological obeisances which might be the price of such, aid) caused Sino-Soviet trade to decline sharply. In 1961 this exchange vaa only two-fifths of the 1959 peak. In view of the aihitious industrialization program envieaged by t1 Chinese leadership, Soviet financial assistance to China cannot be characterized as having been extensive. While the value of the equipment involved in the projected 291 indus- trial installations has been estimated at $3.3 billion, the pay- ment for much of this equipment was apparently scheduled out of current Chinese export earninge. During the first half of the 1950's the USSR extended China some $1.3 billion in financial assistanoe, only part of which wee designated for economic pur- poses. Practically all of these credits had been utilized by the Chinese, by 1956 and the Soviet equipment movipg under the technical assistance program since that time has had to be financed out of current Chinese export earnings. No other assistance vas provided until 1961 .hen the USSR, recognising 4,o Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 that Mana could not settle its accumulated trade indebtedness of $320 ?Approved For Release 2000/04/18 ? CIA-RDP79T01049A002.601g1M11-1 million, funded this debt .over d period of rive years. A providing $40 million vorth of sugar on credit, however, the ;JSSR did nothing to facilitate China's anuisition of badly-needed commodities and foodstuffs in 1961. Thus, Jae total of Soviet credits extended to Chi= since 1950 has amounted to about $1.7 billion, a sum roughly equivalent to Soviet credits and grants extended to the small. Asian Bloc countries of Mongolia, North Vietnaut, and North Korea.* Table?7 Soviet Trade with Communi. t China 1950-1461 lion Tt Year levorte %Mal 33a7ance 1450 388 188 576 +200 1951 476 332 808 + 144 1.952 554 414 968 +140 1953 698 475 1,173 +223 1954 759 578 1,337 +18]. /955 748 644 1,392 +104 1956 733 764 1,497 -31 1957 544 738 1,282 -194 1950 634 881 1,515 .247 1959 955 1,100 2,055 -145 1960 817 848 1,665 -31 1961 367 552. 418 4E14 41-2rsubstearbiaThrease in extensions of credits and grants to these countries by both the USSR (about $500 million in 1960-61) and China (about $300 million) emy have been attributable to Sino-Soviet competition for the fealty of these countries. The outcome of the competition with respect to NOngolia appears to have been resolved in favor of the USSR as testified by the resent adherence or Iftgolla to CRNA. Approved For Release 2000/04/18.: eA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 The statistics of Sino Soviet trade reflect the eagariasof Soviet-Chinese economic relations (see Table 7). These show a relatively steady increase in the volume of trade between these two countries until 1959 and then a sharp decline beginning in 1960. As indicated in the table, the level of trade in 1961 marked, a 10-year low in Sino-Soviet exchange. Reflected in the trade balance figures is the Chinese utilization of Soviet credits In the early period and repayments beginning in 1956. According to Chinese budget figures, repayments by the end of 1960 amounted to scam $800 million, leaving about $900 million yet to be repaid. The commodities exchanged in Soviet-Chinese trade re- present essentially an exchange of Soviet machinery and equipment for Chinese raw materials and consumer goods.. This pattern re- flects Soviet-Chinese trade tbreughout the period until 1961 when Soviet exports of equipment and Chinese exports of food dropped sharply as a result of Chinese economic difficulties. In 1961, Soviet exports of machinery and, equipment to China dropped by some 000 million and amounted to less than 30 percent of total exports while Soviet exports of petroleum, maintained at the same absolute limit, rose to almost 50 percent of total Soviet exports. Soviet imports of food dropped almost to zero. imorts of manufactured consumer goods also declined somewhat, but accounted for almost two-thirds of the total in a smaller volume of total imports frail China. 1;2 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 'Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 ? IV. Trade with the Free World A. The Traditional Pattern 1. plcaiZgom_eadiVS.....igit_to_nof Trade with usnwest Soviet ecanam c intercourse with inftstrialized non-Communist countries has always represented a time-saving device, for trade has made possible a rapid shift from an obeolete to a modern, more productive technology in a large nuMber of industries. So long as same part of the Soviet economy lags technologically behind the West, the USSR will always have available a ready device for buoying its growth rate. In shifting to a more advanced ????? i.e., more productive -- technology, the Soviet Union borrows all the resources, including time, that must go into the research and development of more efficient techniques. Soviet trade with the Industrial West today com- prises the same type of exchange with the same kind of problems as that of the late 1920's. Soviet aviculture' goods and raw materials are exported to pay for the technology embodied in Western machinery. Xn addition Soviet exports mist earn sufficient foreign exchange to pay for the services of Western transport facilities and certain indUstrial raw materials not produced in sufficient quantity within tIle USSR. Any economy whose resources areiconsistently as faly utilized as are those of the USSR is sUbjedt to overt or repressed iaflationary. pressures. In the case ,of the :USSR repremJ La- flation has long been manifest in the chronic tendency of imports - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 to outrun exports with the accompanying chronic necessity for an export of gold. Tl e fact that the commodity composition of Soviet trade with the Industrial West has remained virtualLyymeltered over the past three decades, despite great changes in the volume aM composition of domestic output, is indirectly the result of these chrOnic inflationarypmessures. The Soviet economy, subject to full resource utilization, high investment and rapid growth, is taut; it is an economy of shortages, one which we would des- cribe as a "sellers' market." Because of pervasive and persistent shortages, no energy need be devoted to selling or marketing; rather, buyers seek out sellers, often on a black rbet '4th the offer of Messily high prices. Although the Soviets have prawn themselves to be experienced bargeiters in a situation of bilateral moricrpoly, they remain inexperienced sellers in a competitive enrket of differentiated products. Thus, although their own out- put of highly fabricated goods, especially producer's goods, is now a much larger proportion of total product than it was 3 decades ago, their exports to the developed countries of the West continue to be composed almost entirely of raw materials. The composition of their exports has been stable because they undble -- or unwilling -- to develop the selling and service organization necessary to market their highly fabricatediumducts. It is easier, and therefore in the short-run yields a greater - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 return in net foreign exchange receipts, for the USSR to continue to export the great staple raw materials. 2. Preference for Predictable Markets There are in the West highly organized. markets (for uheat or cotton, for example) where the total volume of the commo- dity perchased and Gold is so great, and the numbers of buyers and sellers active in the market so large that Soviet exports can normal.lyte absorbed without causing a flurry. In dealing in such markets Soviet selling costs are kept to a M111110111M and their net foreign exchange receipts are that much larger. Moreover, because Soviet exports are a small part of the total supplies traded on these markets, the USSR can expand significantly the amount it offers for sale there without depressing price. These sextets are additionally attractive to the USSR because the ability to predict with same certainty* the quantity that must be sold in order to earn the necessary foreign exchange is a great advantage for a planned economy. This same stability and predictability characterizes the market for petroleum, aluminum, tin, and dianonds, commodities nffered in increasing quantities by USSR in recent years. These are atiededstAtredsmrkets where prices remain stable over relatively long periods of tine and where the quantities of the commodity handled are subject to fairly rigid direct or indirect controls administered by the sellers. In order to .in access to' such markets, the USSR has often bad to lower prices enough Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 *Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 to attract marginal buyers. These bargain prices have caused con- siderable concern in the West that the USSR vas attempting to disrupt the order of the market. Actually, however, a careful study of Soviet behavior in these cases indicates tbat after Soviet sales at bargin prices have attained the desired volume, the USSR hes quietly raised its prices to the level of the market. It seems quite likely that no one was more surprised than Soviet exporters when in 1958 Soviet sales of tin were so large as to cause the temporary suspension of the International Tin Agree- mut. in contrast, Soviet market research in such fields as aluminum, diamonds, flax, and, atne'seems tO have been of mnehtigher quality. Additional quantities of these and other materials have been successfunyearteted In the West, either with no depressing effect on price or with only a temporary price reduction. 3. Chronic Problems of Finance Despite expanding raw naterial sales, Soviet fOreign exchange earnings have consistently fallen abort of the require- mmrts of their import program. Since 1950 the USSR has been forced to sell nearly $2 billion in gold to settle its interna- tional accounts. Soviet gold holdings and Soviet gold production are state secrets of the highest order, known prObablycely to a very taw of the Kremlin leaders. Although Soviet spokmasnlhave done r)thing to discourage Western apeculation of an immense hoard of Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 'Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 gold in Moscow which is annually enriched by a huge flaw fran current output, the fact remains that Soviet behavior in interna- tional markets is not that of a countzipossessed of a large reserve. The assiduousness with which they bave cultivated their reputation in international commercial circles, the promptness with which they have filled contracts, the eagerness with which they have pursued new trade contacts bespeak their lang-run interest in internatianal trade with the West. The vigor of their bargaining over price, their attempts to tie imports to exports, their recent search for medium-term credits of increasingly long, dhration? their pressure for most-Zavored-nation treatment fran the West, above all the unpredictable composition of their raw mterial exports which suggests an annual harrying search for additional foreign exchange earners -- all these bespeak an attempt to conserve what gpld they have. In addition, gold production appears to be a relatively expensive operation within the USSR, rankirig gold sales at the fixed price of $35 an ounce an exceedingly expensive means of settling international accounts. Itt thus appears that Soviet eagerness to wall more to the West is a genuine concern about the an of financing their imports. Despite this concern, however, Soviet trade ?Triclinia have given no indication of knowing what to do about it. The only devices for increasing sales in the industrial countries of the Free World of which they woos to be aware are participation Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 in monopolistic agreertmnts or bargain prices. They have gime no Indication of a willingness to make the Investment in time and resources neceesery for successful marketing of their highly fabricated goods at competitive rather than cut-throat prices. Oh the other 1n4 the ;tromptness with which theyhaveraised prices once this device has produced the desired result is a strong indication of their interest in minimizing the cost of acquiring foreign exchange. B. The Economic Offensive Since the mid-1950's the expansion of Soviet economic relations with the underdeveloped countries of the Free World has been 12 most dramatic of the many dynamic developments charac- terizing total Soviet foreign trade.. Until the shift from a defensive to an aggressive foreign economic policy, Soviet trade with these areas amounted to only about five percent of total Soviet trade, and to one-quarter of Soviet trade with the Free World. By 1962, however, trade with these areas had grown to 15 percent of total trade, and to nearly 45 percent of Soviet- Free World trade. The rapid expansion of commmlityexchange between the USSR and these areas was acconeanied by an equally rapid expansion of other contacts, economic, cultural and political. The number of Soviet technicians working an various developmental projects in underdeveloped countries has grown to nearly 7,000 while the number of students and trainees from these - 48 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 areas in schools or institutes in the USSR has similarly mush- roomed. Whole armies have been provided with Soviet military equipment and trained in Soviet military techniques, and delega- tions of various sorts constantly travel back and forth between the Bloc and the underdeveloped countries. All this is a eery great change. Before the onslaught of the economic offensive, Soviet interest in these areas was probably equally great, but its ability to implement the interest was limited by domestic priorities. Economic contacts were largely confined to commerce, and commerce was primarily the purchase. of certain materials -- rubber, cotton, wool for *OM* cash. An export surplus in Soviet trade with the Industrial West was used to finance imports primarily from the outer sterling area. The Soviet economic offensive is an integral part of Soviet foreign policy to extend Soviet influence. The uncommitted and politicalkynmetable countries of the Free World, most of vhichhave recently emergmi from colonial rale with a legacy of anti-Western sentiment, have offered the Communists the "weakest links" through which the political and economic encirclement of Europe and the political isolation of the US could be accomplished. The immediate Soviet ambition has been to eradicate Western influence in these newly independent areas and simultaneously to render them increasingly vulnerable to Commies. At the same 119 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 time the Ccemunitte have hoped to create economic pressures in Western industrialized countries which are presumed to be depen- dent on underdeveloped areas for markets and sources of supply. The economic offensive has employed a variety of techniques to accomplish its ends. It bas been characterized by a. pragmatic eclecticism in which offers of trade and various forms of aid have been combined with propaganda, subversion and political support. It has provided a vide variety of arms and militery eqpipnent on credit, the signing of the military agree- ments being ftaiowed very promptly by the shipment of the equip- ment and dispatch of Soviet technicians to train the recipients in its use. The USSR has offered lines of credit fer economic development, typically $130 million at 2i percent for 12 years. Most of Soviet foreign aid has specified repayment in either the exports of the country or in convertible currency, the form to be determinelbynegotiation at the ties repayment is due. Soviet economic aid has been used to construct projects as sizeable as the Aswan Dam or the Bhilai steel mill, and as modest as small cement plants or work shops. A significant proportion of total ald expenditures to date has been used to finance the services of Soviet technicians and specialists of all kieds. Soviet geologists have surveyed the natural resources of countries from Ghana and Egypt, through Iraq, Afghanistan anl )1edia to Nepal; Soviet advisors have been active in key govern- mute]. Minietries and Soviet engineers have erected a great -50- Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 variety of industrial installations and trained indigenous vopula- tions in their use. The economic offensive has been supported by a propaganda barrage equally diverse in its composition. Radio broadcasts in the tongues of Africa, the sums sast, Asia and Latin America have multiplied in number, printed matter has been distributed directly to literate populations, books and periodicals in native languages have been made available to local dealers at token prices and wsprint has been sold to yOblishere at prices which could not fail to curry favor. In addition a progrmm of scholarships for study in the USSR has brought nearly 6,000 students from Asia, Africa and Latin America to the USSR since its inception. Although the USSR has served as the leader and prime mover, this program. to yin the underdeveloped countries from the Wast is a Bloc-wide effort. The USSR accounts for about three- %afters of the total effort, while the European Satellites have supporbed the Soviet economic thrust and Communist Ohina has ergaged in a smaller foreign aid program of its own, largely restricted to Southeast Asia. The countries of Eestern Europe appear to participate in the aid program both on their awn account and as subcontractors and suppliers to the USSR. Since 1959 and 19600 the peak years of the Soviet economic aid programs the emphasis in Soviet foreign aid has ahifted back to military aid and technical training. From the - 51 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Apr= fir Rttata2240118 : q1A-RDU9srlap4a8216=1)201-1seen with minimum costs. First, countries seeking arms are often deeply embroiled in a dispute, domestic or foreign, and therefore in the state of turmoil in which Communist agitation gains most adherents. Second, the sale of arms, on current or deferred payment terms, costs the USSR little. If the military equipment sold is obsolete in the USSR, as has often been the case, its opportunity cost is zero, for it has already been superseded by an improved model. If the equipment is in current production* then the amount provided to the underdeveloped countries is likely to be such a small fraction of total output that its opportunity cost is slight. In contrast, the opportunities for domestic use of the resources going into a modern integrated steel plant, Which are foregone when the plant is sold on credit to another country, would be much more significant to Soviet economic planners. Perhaps of prime importance is the potential impact of Soviet eillimalressistance to underdeveloped countries on the unity and cohesiveness of the Western flied powers. The prospect of a politically as well as an economically United Europe has not only become more imminent in recent months, but more formidable from the Soviet viewpoint for two reasons. The first is Britain's recently evidenced willingness to place ties with the six con- tinental countries of the European Economic Community ahead of existing ties with mothers of the Commonwealth and the European Free lisade Area, both of which were created by the British. - 52 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 'Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 British participation will mean a more potent EUropean Community, econoodeally and politically. The second lies in the fact that Communist parties all over the world are deeply divided into 2 groups: those who favor traditional, Stalinist policies and those mo-caassioists of the Coumunist movement who support Ehrushelevis revision of the Doctrine. The approach to Western unity could not come at a ore uncomfortable time for the Kremlin leaders, struggling as they are with a fracture in their erstwhile monolithic body politic. Thus Mbeeow, while acting to reinforce the economic end political bonds existing in Eastern Europe, would place a special premium in any current development which midht promote diviseirness among the Western allies. If the provision of arms to Xndonesia could so examebate the West Irian issue as to cause a plit between the Dutch and their Western allies, Moscow would undoubtedly consider the r.seward ample to cover its costs. And if the installation of medium range missiles an the island of Cuba could make the US _11(Wcttuf- ih the world arena, economic calculus would be considered irrelevant. Soviet Bloc trade with the underdeveloped countries has been atimulalad both indirectly by the existence of Soviet aid and the fact of more extensive contacts and directly by Soviet and Satellite offers to buy and actual purchases of the major exportn of these countries. The Soviet Bloc has sometimes contracted to "bm, nearly the entire annual production of the single -53- Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 ? Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 or most important export of a country dependent on export receipts, and has timed the offer to coincide with a period When the world price of the commodityr Was especie14 depressed. In this way it has become the major trading partner of Guinea, Egypt, Nhli and Cuba. It has further signed long-tarm trade and payments agree- ments providing for the barter of raw material exports against Soviet fuel and capital goods. Such agreements are especially attractive to the underdeveloped countries Whose imports of capital and consumer goods are dependent on export receipts Which have fluctuated rather violently with the world price of their export commodity. As a result Soviet commodity exohange with the underde- veloped countries has grown at a rate of 30 percent ayear since 1955. Cotton, rubber and sugar account for 68 percent of total Soviet imports from these countries. Soviet exports Show a similarly concentrated commodity composition, with machinery and petroleum representing one-half of the total. Poughly two- fifths of Soviet exports to these areas represents credit financed exports moving under the aid program bile about one.fifth of Soviet imports represents repayment of past credits, mainly Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Table 8 USSR Stade with Underdeveloped Countries in 1961 Millions of Dollars and Percent des...wallall..4101......1.01.elowneerarem?00.0.11011, Value Percent 11?1?Mill!CONIMICIIMPI?11 Total Exports ? 319.2 100.0 Machinery and Equipment Complete Plants wo-.9 17.2 Petroleum and Petroleum Products 3.19.6 3.46 Rolled Ferrous btale 49.4 6.0 Wood and Wood Products 58.8 7.2 Food 83.6 10.2 Other Xhrchandise 206.1 25.2 Total Imports 950.7 l0000 Cotton 122.0 228 Ebbers Natural Wt.8 23.6 Food 4?342 43.4 Non-farrous Metals 30.0 3.2 Other Merchandise i70.7 18.o INS;01.1494.1111=13.. The patbzrn of Soviet ttade within the underdeveloped areas in part reflects the concentration of the Soviet economic offensive0 rive countries have received 70 percent of total Soviet economic aid while the entire program embraces two dozen recipients. The- -55- Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/1853aAfDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Economic Credits and GrantsEktended by the USSR to Underdeveloped Countries12/ JantarY 39511-11Tune 1962 Killion US$ 11?01?110111.191?1.....MMIN Wen allas Latin America 400 ......amnaprommwoormonewsemermso Argentina 100 Cuba 300 Middle East ?12. Iraq 180 Syrian Arab Republic 150 Turkey 10 United Arab Republic 510 lemon 25 Africa 420 Ethiopia 100 Ghana 95 Wines 65 Mali 50 Somali Republic 55 Sudan. 25 Tunisia 30 Afghanistan Burma Cambodia Ceylon India Indonesia Nevi Pakistan Iceland 'Yugoslavia 505 10 5 30 810 370 10 35 ao 5 75 a. Data are rounded to the nearest riveo - 56 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 greater importance of Latin America in trade than in aid reflects the lack of receptivity on the part of countries in the area (excepting Cuba) to Soviet aid offers. Soviet interest in the area, however,Windatd in, the volume of commerce. The con,. centration of aid and trade among individual countries 10 14 part a reflection of a few large aid contracts. During the years (2956-58) when Sdviet materials mere being delivered for the construction of the Ebdlai steel plant, India imports from the USSR more than tripled in value. The period of heavy deliveries of Soviet goods for the Aswan Dam began in 3961. Table 10 Distribution of Soviet Foreign Wade in 1961 and Aid with Free World Underdeveloped Countries in 1954-62 vooseatereimIlowomm Nallion of dollars and Percent of Total Area Ebreign Trade (1961) Economic Aid Deliveries Value _122442 PercentValue Percent ? ?. Tbtea pi 1,769 100 882 100 Latin America 667 38 52 6 Middle East 368 23. 269 30 Africa 122 7 68 8 Asia 502 28 has 47 Europe 109 6 75 9 a, BeTarairar-'roundco-a-r?ponent---smaynot add to the totAs Awn. - 57 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Concentration of Soviet aid in a few countries reflects also an increasing selectivitr on the part of the USSR. Although aid has always been concentrated among a few recipients, in the early* years of the program, its scope and distribution were probably more limited by lack of receptivity on the part of the underdeveloped countries than by Soviet choice. As the program has grown, as projects have been successfull,y implemented with no more than normal delays and missteps, and above all since the Soviet sputniks have endowed the USSR with a new aura of strength and respectability, the number of countries willing to accept Soviet aid has also grown. 2he degree of concentration, however, has remained about the same. At present the Soviet aid program le concentrated in countries of strategic geographic location like Afghanistan, strategic international significance like India, CT countries considered ripe for ?socialism" like Cuba. For example, since 1960 when the Castro regime in Cuba adopted an "anti-Imperialist- foreign policy, and nationalised the means of production, more than one-quarter of total Soviet aid extensions has gone to Cuba alone. Soviet foreign aid has -become an accepted tact of life , 44-caa/tAt, Ug474:-, 231 the underdeveloped world; in tact, it is generally/lability it-?"4 j'" ' to provide up-to-date industrial equipment and training of all kinds. Since it hes established itself, the USSR can now afford Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 'Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 to be more selective in dispensing its munifimance. It seems likely that in the future the Soviet economic aid program will ebb and flaw in intensity, continuing at less than remit levels until the USSR sees a new opportunity for an important potential addition to the Communist fold. - 59 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 APPENDIX TABLBS Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T010419A002600010001-1 Appro d F r Rtl se:Am:mm(189. MA-411MF'79ff111005)0CP26,0001 001-1 gl 1m ri '4"? :" qiICI M O 0*ICIP.1 t1743% N t".' roU %003 ^0. 00$40; 8.; tgol gM EP 4 44 gl 1m? 9w: 9R (?-at 09 c!?? c:0 141 as va moq kA 3Y ?ki 44 44 44 44 aa 0 0 0 42 ;:f3 lkt! ^9 c?9 179 c"? -4'. dm SI :4\4 r& t; 0, 11 9cm tr,m ^ 4* rg* ct 91 Si' -4; Ei C-4 (S1 4 19 179 aZil (1:7 . ? 174' Ia.% ag tco te% ga 3W 44 44 074 WW a, (no, gtr. 91 -19 91 t".*4; '"\I! ?;""? I A M M a 04 0 ig C6.3. &a aa ,,,,,,, AA -IPA .4'A AA Cl . ro? 0 ? 4 CO. ." .9 ? ? 9 Cr1? ? ag g 3g 111 1g au dtw ob ob, a IP. is MM MM UNI^ tAtiN LAW% ilhiJiIIIIJiII GO Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Table 12 Commodity Composition of Soviet Exports 1955-1961 ? 73 ......eni...........?????momememAttlietanglai.W 1 ..ThMartt., ''' 'AA...1:Zr mo =M.* 4...a....1.1.1. Am...* ...........-... 3 . ..._ 2_ 22_ 1756 __ 2.0j_ ___L.2,8 22.22_ 1960 < A .0 M a Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Anent -11 O AA -'Total 7Apert3 ti, 3,426.6 100.0 1ALLI 100.0 122121 loox IlLE211 100.0 LA122,1 100.0 5,561.6 100.0 ilv.za x -71----- %lag)) chinery and Equipment 22212, siiak 624.4 na, 0.221.3.21,2 /A,8_111 1.3.68.1 2145. 1,141.2 204 564.6 Li U) a) O Complete Plants 276.8 8.1 299.6 8.3 321.9 7.3 339.9 7.9 569.1 10.5 568.5 10.2 355.8 T5.9 K3 K3 C) &Vele, Lubricants and c) 25 Related Materials 329.0 2j. 428.2 11.8 .61.1.1 14.8 651.2 15.2. 797.8 Via 902.5 16.2 1 046.1 grA 44 ' cl; Coal and Coke 97.8 2.9 142.8 4.0 249.5 5.7 219.8 5.1 229.1 4.2 242.1 4.4 284.9 !.7 .. Petroleum and Petroleum co CI Products 230.1 6.7 284.4 7.9 397.6 9.1 429.9 10.0 567.0 10.4 657.9 11.8 757.8 y.6 5; 330res and Concentrates 115A Iit 130.02.6 gad 4.2 190.0 4.4 215.2 4.0 242l2 4.4 252.6 F4.2 7:1- 0 0 O 3 1 Iron re .4 81.6 2.4 86.5 2.4 124.9 2.8 137.4 3.2 154.3 2.8 175.0 3.1 187.8 CAD gftlie Metals and Manufactures lea& 12.6 Au 3.5.0. 2.2.41 ilta ....11 16.1 743.1 ma 837.2 1.2.4 W...1.2 k2.21 a 4=. Ferrous Metals 321.0 9.4 385.7 10.7 439.6 10.0 494.5 11.5 547.2 10.1 642.3 11.5 711.7 E.1) to > Rolled Ferrous Metals 192.2 5.6 233.6 6.5 267.9 6.1 329.9 7.7 366.2 6.7 428.8 7.7 478.2 c) > c) c) K3 Mon-Ferrous Meals 110.7 3.2 157.3 4.4 202.9 4.6 197.6 4.6 195.9 3.6 194.9 3.5 211.1 23.5 CD Aluminum 19.4 0.6 31.8 0.9 43.8 1.0 56.6 1.3 38.7 0.7 44.7 0.6 58.2 cD1.0 c) 1 c) in 6.2 0.2c) 7.1 0.2 37.6 0.8 44.5 1.0 38.4 0.7 24.6 0.4 12.2 c)0.2 c) _.% c) _.% 2:See footnote at sad of table. 0 Aical 'iiood and(Wood Products i CD Lumber 8 ._.extile Raw Materials and co Semi-manufactures 346.1 10.1 329.2 la 305.0 7.,2 223,:8 6.8 308.0 la 358.6 6.4 364.9 gll 297.9 8.7 272.4 7.5 255.5 5.8 238.6 5.6 248.1 4.6 288.7 5.2 283.8 g.7 4* X4Consuner Goods iTa Via 476.8 1,31 917.7 22,2 665.4 1241 953.5 1/12. m...2 16.2 I 006.5 ate C3 C) 11 ".4 Food 386.4 11.2 369.2 10.2 773.6 17.6 507.7 11.8 755.9 14.6 699.0 12.6 790.4 5173.2 -1 Grain 283.5 8.3 226.7 6.3 566.0 12.9 358.8 8.3 487.2 9.0 467.8 8.4 473.8 337.9 co c) E3 4. CD Otlaer-Consumer Goods 111.4 3.3 107.6 3.0 144.1 3.3 257.7 3.7 157.7 2.9 203.2 3.7 216.1 ;313.6 _.% > Other Merchanlise 164.8 4.8 179.3 2.7.9. Etta 4.1 EU 4.1 gia 4.1 204.4 la .2.19.2 2.31 a a tn.) Ulm:Specified ?2EA 22,a 660.2 2041 ZIA 12.0 478.4 11.2 647.4 21:2 528- ..2.:1 ,,,..1 ck? 0 ? CD CD 4. because of rounding, composenets Nei atria to the totals shown. -.% a a Table 12 Commodity Coupositioa of Soviet Exports 1955-1961 (Continued) Million US$ and Percent of TOol 1$57 mit_ Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Pe4nt mi 2.1 82.1 2.3 2zik 161.7/2,2. 231.1 94.3 2.8 86.0 2.4 135.1 2.2 111.2 2.6 211 240.9 2,.?. 3.1 136.9 3.2 122.1 2.2 lam 212, 163.5 42.7 2?.9 4.8 05.1 161-7 150.4 2.8 182.8 3.3 206.5CD go, 8 ? Cotton a 0 I.-1.0001.0009n Table 13 Commodity Composition of Soviet Imports 1955-1961 -a 3 m--- Million US$ snd Percent of_wl sa. 13 ni -----1226.--.. 122/ 101---- -----1W.......... _1*..2.1-- ---____23--- 9. < M Vsame Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value PerRent CD 11 cu (Motel Imports a/ 14241 100.0 Ia.E4i 100.0 alma 100.0 iietka 100.0 2421u 100.0 24.311:26 100.0 2422a loo.o 0 Ochinery and Equipteut c) g Transportation Equipment 8 t?Puelss Lubricants and co Related Materials _.(1, Coal and Coke ,1$1 Petroleum and Petroleum XI; Products C, -a ..,,Ores and Concentrates UD -I ?Base Metals and Manufactures 2e24a 386.3 222. 12.5 825.5 424.2 250.0 8.2 256.4 126.9 4.1 118.8 123.1 4.0 137.5 251.3 8.2 374.6 204.1 ill 288.3 71.0 2.3 145.2 16.1 0.5 88.4 133.1 4.3 143.1 47.9 1.6 32.4 43.5 1.4 46.2 24.8 940.4 3.10.2 ma& Ria 3,321,2 26.6 1,675.2 9.8 1,729.0 *Li 11.6 407.3 10.3 427.2 9.8 542.4 10.7 658.1 la 208.1 LI 212.2I212 Eal 4.6 237., 77.0 8.6 1.8 85.7 135.2 3.1 145.6 403.5 2.1 331.0 326.5 la 1135.0 183.4 4.2 265.2 127.8 2.9 222.0 133.1 3.1 169.9 39.5 0.9 41.8 54.5 1.3 74.3 _22.28, 1.3. mu 11.7 534.3 4.2 217.0 1.7 93.6 2.6 123.4 26 280.2 21 50.5 6.6 342.0 3.2 160.4 3.1 163.5 0.6 22.5 1.3 53.0 1:2. ;37 .7 3.3 88.7 2.3 3.8 119.4 34 10.4 1222:1 ma 8.0 Ma Li -L17- CD 4' Ferrous Metals U3 > Rolled Ferrous Metals CD C3 IN) Ron-Ferrous Metals CD c) Tin c) copper CD -.% 4.0 2.4 4.0 0.9 1.3 a a Chemicals 2aa.in.,/ mi. 2.1 a -, 2.% See footnote at end of table. 163.5 4.2 119.5 3.0 127.6 3.2 45.5 1.2 44.2 1.1 7.0.11 12 1.7 93.5 2.9 143.7 .6...2, 314.0 a./ 5.2 373.9 2.4 178.8 3.3 172.0 0.8 34.8 1.5 71.9 2.2 1.19..j. Cg5.9 ,742.8 8 .A.2.8 ").o.4 00.9 C3 tv o 0 0 Table 13 Commodity Composition of Soviet Imports 1955-1961 I> (Continued) 73 -0 Million US$ and Percent of 4tta Am...er ...m.0.12?401Crab a le9 5 122? M7 120.____ 1.?5_2___ 1960 __2_1_96-1 m 11 91 X awbber atd Rubber fto lets o) a) Wood and Wood Products m Ceextile Raw Materials and a a Semi-manufactures it Cotton g Wool gkonsumer Goods U Food C/ Other Consumer Goods .4 Other erchandise m M c) Unspecified cm Value Percent Value 41.4 1.4 124.8 Z.,2 3.19. ma 166.4 21,11 216.3 20.1 0.7 54.0 89.7 2.9 90.0 0112 21.6 Liglia 517.1 16.9 487.5 144,8 4.7 336.8 308.6 10.1 365.8 106.5 .8.12 Percent 12. 19. 6.o 1.5 2.5 22.8 13.5 9.3 10.1 Value Percent Value 127.7 1.1 21 8.1 182.2 )494.,?, 347.8 104.8 309.3 122.9 127.7 211,2 480.4 433.5 3,22a. 3.1 3.2 32 135.2 107.7 1,161.3 12.2 11.0 10.1 559.9 601.5 397.6 m Percent Value Percent Value Tampa Value itAls 0 _ 2,2 , 1.2. Aa 4.2 IOLA .196.2 g/2,i o) 2.4 A.2 1.....2 lo4.8 2..12 124.3 v.i. 116...._ 0 m /11 394 LE 364.4, .6,A 30.4 0.2. 3.1 163.9 3.2 179.9 3.2 130.1 4.2 2.5 100.8 2.0 118.0 2.1 103.8 21.8 2.6.1/ 1,436.5 28.?2 1,577.3 28.0 1,782.6 %.1.6 12.9 542.7 10.7 611.8 10.9 776.0 z3.3 13.8 893.8 17.6 965.6 17.2 1,006.6 117.3 21. 450.7 fia 378.8 .6..a 3!e1.3 23 2211.? 2.2 107.2 2.1 2541 LI 327.8 ? >a. Because of rounding, components nay not add to the totals shown. a a a a a a a a 1.- 1.000 1.0009ZOOV6P -0 -0 .4319.0e,yeslesoluontssevaoniweaaW CD Table 3.14. Commodity Composition of Soviet exports to European Satellites 1955-1961 1955 1956 1957 1958 125.2____ m a 9, Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Pent (To --.1r"....- fota1 Exports W 1,792.1 100.0 li.Vizi 100.0 2,549.9 100.0 11222., 100.0 2,950.5 100.0 3411/1 100.0 3,420.1 100.0 .....nr-, &achinery and Equipment iO4.4 112 218.1 1.113 220.2 8.6 248.4 .1.:_70. 368.5 Ea 414.2 lu. 459.2 ila K3 c) Complete Plants 129.7 7.2 65.4 3.7 50.4 2.0 51.5 202 87.5 3.0 108.6 3.5 111.3 i/i.3 c) c) c) awls, Lubricants and c) 2zRelated Materials 120.4 LI 163.9 la MA 12.1 321:11 ia....0 351.3 1.1....2 413.7 21.12 486.4 ta co i.../ Coal and Coke 64.3 3.6 90.1 5.1 176.8 6.9 153.9 6.6 162.5 5.5 171.2 5.5 204.2 Petroleum and Petroleum *0 Products 55.1 3.1 72.8 4.1 135.6 5.3 146.3 6.3 187.1 6.3 240.7 7.7 280.2 Eb.2 > Q ...yea and Concentrates 102.3 la Mil 6.o 153.2 6.0 163.9 7.1 197.0 6.3 206.6 6.6 218.4 i6.4 I3--- CAD T -i Iron Ore c) 81.6 4:6 86.5 4.9 124.9 4.9 135.2 5.8 151.3 5.1 170.8 5.5 184.1 J.4 ?Base Metals and Manufactures al22,11 .Dh CAD 122 02.2 17.11415.216j.3. V.5.2 .. a.1 22.?.2. EA .._,..1 &a titi p ? c) Ferrous Metals 164.3 9.2 193.0 10.9 273.4 10.7 345.8 14.9 392.3 13.3 451.7 14.5 509.7 ts.9 CD K3 Rolled Ferrous Metals 97.0 5.4 118.2 6.7 173.1 6.8 239.7 10.3 280.8 9.5 328.2 10.5 375.2 gi..0 CD c) Mon-Ferrous Metals 85.3 4.8 109.2 6.2 141.9 5.6 109.4 4.7 128.2 4.3 132.4 4.2 145.7 &.3 c) c) _.% Aluminum 13.3 0.7 13.7 0.8 25.0 1.0 24.4 LI 21,7 NZ 30.8 54 4547 0-3 c) Tin 5.9 0.3 -4.5 0.3 13.5 0.5 8.1 0.3 8.8 0.3 6.3 0.2 7.8 c) c) --lbaliemicals _.% ga 2.0 .12/7 _AWL AWL 1,41, 52.8 2.3 58.3 2.0 63.2 2.0 Lk? a.2 I> Million US* and Percent of iitel a. 1960 1964 See footnote at end of table. CD Value Percent ET u) wood and Wood Products 311 1.1 CD K3 c) Lumber 4.0 0.2 c) C) Textile Raw Materials and -N Semi-manufactures _& o0 .. Cotton kesmaer Goods 4.1142 ALI 233.8 13.0 at2 14.6 12.9 1.3 Ch Food 262.3 Grain 230.4 (.0 a Other Consumer Goods 23.4 0,0ther Merchandise c.o 68.0 Unspecified a C1) a a. Because Of rOtill a 0 12:2 Table 14 Commodity Composition of Soviet Exports to European Satellites 1955-1961 (Continued) 1957 Value Percent Value Percent Value 2.0 84.6 la 8..2z2 14.3 0.8 43.9 1.7 46.7 262.2 14.8 1111i 221 243.9 229.7 13.0 215.0 8.4 208.3 241.2 13.6 667.9 26.2 423.8 207.1 11.7 597.6 23.4 349.2 121.9 6.9 457.0 17.9 269.8 34.1 1.9 70.2 2.8 74.7 82.1 4.6 81.1 ?La 66.1 316.0, 1112 ALE! 12.4 13 13 Million US0e2..Rdiertof491FILi 1958 1959 i6o 1 11 Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Pacent 87.. 04/ 117.0 2. CD 2.0 49.6 1.7 58.6 1.9 68.8 02 CD? Eta 241.8 90 204.1 18.3 660.2 15.1 586.4 11.6 353.7 3.2 73.8 2.8 at2 12.1 SLR 8.2 283.2 22211 6.9 234.0 7.5 231.4 22.4 575.7 '13.3 19.9 497.7 16.0 428.6 12.0 352.6 11.3 279.0 2.5 78.0 2.5 84.8 910e its! 3?2,2 12.3 489.8 K3 C) g 8.6 a it 6.8 Co ?c3.1.2 4732.5 8.2 0 2.5 (I) ca4. omponen S may no 1.- 1.000 1.0009Z0 Table 15 Commodity Composition of Soviet Imports from European Satellites 1955-1961 -a Million US and Percent ofa. Trital 11 ___ ------Mi---- 1957 al 12 2 _ 1264 22.-- ----.--- S';' Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Perient (T 0 Eotal Imports 2./ 1 662.8 100.0 21212.1.2 100.0 2.1,914.8 100.0 2,205.7 100.0 &laza 100.0 Raaa 100.0 0,654f 100.0 ryachinery and. F.quipment 733.644.1 .p...12 26.11. 72,12, ma 863..6 3.2....1 1,040.0 ALI 1,286 0. 82 bata - la. 6 1 g Transportation Equipment 274.6 16.5 269.3 14.8 302.8 15.8 339.7 15.4 422.3 16.8 532.2 18.9 455.2 14.8 c) K3 a a 4=Fue1s, Lubricants and a Flo Related Materials 233.9 14.1 OA 12.6 184.6 11 190.1 8.6 209.10. lia glo, iff 1984 al 4b. 't g Coal and Coke 121.4 7.3 116.6 6.4 86.4 4.5 74.1 3.4 83.0 3.3 90.9 3.2 91.2 4.0 p" Petroleum and Petroleum ,Products 112.6 6.8 111.2 6.1 98.1 5.1 116.0 5.3 126.1 5.0 124.8 4.4 1o6.9 c$.5 I::' 5; :50re5 and Concentrates 152.9 2..s. 152.5 8.4 140.7 L.3, 160.8 La 122.0 4,8 102.4 1.6 21.2 its. 0 Ise* Metals and Manufactures 37.2 2.2 22:.?. 2.2 3271i. 1.6 2241. 1.6 2?22. 2.2 ..:_fl Inli 126.3 .P. Ferrous Metals 11.0 0.7 13.2 0.7 17.4 0.9 25.6 1.2 44.8 1.8 80.3 2.8 109.7 3 a .6 ROLled Ferrous Metals 4 8 0.3 5.9 0.3 11.2 0.6 10.1 0.5 9.6 o.4 21.8 0.8 35.2 CD tg .Ph C) CD K3 Non-Ferrous *tale 26.3 1.6 26.4 1.5 13.0 0.7 9.4 0.4 11.4 0.5 14.6 0.5 16.5 53.5 c) Copper 0.3 negl. 0.2 negl. 0.1 negl. 0.2 nogl. 042 negl. 0.1 nag]. 0.1 anel c, K3 c) Chemicals c) ALI 2 a 2 74.1..).i 2.2 A.?. 1.8 41.8 1,2 2.2,Aco a 2.1 08 Ra 83.8 soli a Rubber end Rubber Products 3.2ta 12 3.1 0.8 RA 0.9 .1.21,? 12 at.?. 0.8 -4, 21,2 0.8 24.2 00.8 c) spe footnote at end of table. Table 15 Commodity Composition of Soviet Imports from European Satellites 1955-1961 (Continued) 3 Million US sod Percent of CD 4=k a > a K.1 a co a a K.1 a co aa _% a a a _% a aa _% a . a _% 1956 41?1111?NOMNIM..., 1957 1958 3.959 1960 -11 CD potrai Exports42.1 Table 16 e Percent Value Peicent ci ? 010??????????? on. 7I48 100.0 734.0 100.0 544.1 100.0 634.0 100.0 354.5 100.0 817.1 100.0 167.1 3R0.0 Cal-4,--- Ofachinery and Equipment.?...t. 229.6 MA 304.7 41.6 g/16 9....2 318.0 121 22/1 62.6 20,2 ?la 108.1 6 c) c) Complete Plants 141.5 16.9 216.9 29.6 209.0 38.4 166.2 26.2 399.8 41.9 373.8 45.7 78-9 11..5 c) 8 .--114vo1s, Lubircants and 8 CO Related Materials 32i2 10.6 86.o laa 2221, 16.6 2gA. 14.6 mu 12:1 1.23.1 114 l _3 420.7 a .1 co ii Petroleum and Petroleum ? ? 31 Products 79.0 10.6 86.0 3.1.7 90.4 16.6 92.4 14.6 117.7 22.3 113.1 23.8 120.7 069 31. io Ores and Concentrates 0.2 Ma' 0.2 ma. 0.2 BE22:- 1.2 0.2 L..1 0.1 1.2 0.1 - 0 -.1 C.0"0 -"se Metals and Manufactures e8.u.8 78.1$E4 114).8 au Va 12.1 $4.5 la, 69.8 II 41.2 3a...2. a " -i a Ferrous Metals 60.5 8.3 32.4 6.0 60.9 9.6 48.0 5.0 59-3 34-7 29-4 4=. 75-7 10.1 I..8 co Rolled Ferrous Metals 53.7 7.2 43.7 6.0 21.4 3.9 36.8 5.8 29.4 3.1 39.2 19.3 c:.5.3 4=. > CD a a Non-Ferrous Metals 12.8 1.7 27.9 2.4 8.4 1.5 25.8 2.5 6.4 0.7 10.5 1.3 6.5 )10..8 K.11.6 60.4 CD Aluminum 0.1 meg]. 0.1 meg].. negl. negl. 9.2 1.5 0.2 meg].. 2.6 003 c) K3 o) ?Chemicals 4.8 0.6 2.1 ...9.1. 2.2 0.6 12 o.6 342 0.4 211 1.2 2:1 01.6 a " a a ?Wood and Wood Products 3.2.2 1.6 10.8 2..a 6.0 1.3. 212, 0.1 o.6 0.1 o.8 0.1a .412 8113 " a -0............ Commodity Composition of Soviet Exports to Communist China 1955-1961 Table 16 Commodity Composition of Soviet Exports to Communist China 1955-1961 LSee footnote at end of table. potrai Exports42.1 potrai Exports42.1 LSee footnote at end of table. LSee footnote at end of table. CD a. CD fl) C? onsumer Goods C,) CD K.) Food a a a Table 16 Commodity Composition of Soviet Exports to Communist Chius 1955-1961 (continued) 122.____ Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent La 0.8 6.0 0.8111 1.4 1.0 0.1 0.7 0.1 0.9 0.2 1.1 0.2 1958 1959 Million US aud.Percent of oti 1960 a Other Consumer Goods 5.3 0.7 5.3 0.7 6.8 1.2 8.1 1.3 /96IL nme.ea? 0 Value Peracent 6.6 91.1 ita 0.6 ?:TA m 0.5 0.1 aegis negl. 63.8 S7.4 1%3 C) C) 6.1 0.6 4.7 0.6 3.8 21.0 c) _& .N orther Merchandise 2.13, 1.1 la o.8 3.:_26. 211 11.2 1.8 ad- 165.5 AU 26742 214 214 Ounspecified 322.4 239.1 ..-atk 120.6 22.2 120.9 2211 P3^ a. Because of rounding, components may not add to the totals shown. C) -a C) C) C) 1%3 104 C) C) C) -a C) C) C) -a )3.?????allmuc. Table 17 Cormodity Composition of Soviet Imports from Coenunist China 1955-1961 -0 ...- 3 < _3_,,22,___ 1956 1957 1958 ---_-__10-9-.--. a a_ Value Percent Value Percent %raw Percent Value Percent Yaw Percent -n 01.1043016.0.. 4.49.11M?90?Millin? 0 Elitg 100 11 0 (.4't 2 100 le 0 MA 100.0 883..2 100.03. 1._ cu_LIO. 100.0 = arMacbinery and Equipaant 1.12:2 1.6 22 1.2 6.4 22 ia 2:2, 12.4 1.1 a) cf, (I) Transportation Equipment 10.3 1.6 9.2 1.26.4 0.9 4.3 0.5 12.1 1.1 K.1 a sFuels, Imbricants and a Related Materials 2...,22 0.8 2.1 21,1 1.:2 .22 3.42 sla 2.8 242 2.6 .a. ---4 ? Coal and Coke 5.0 0.8 2.1. 0.3 1.9 0.32.8 0.3 2.7 0.2 2.6 .H Petroleum and Petroleum 0?Products .. ., nee.. nee. .. - 0.2 neg3.. 0.1 neg3.. F. i30ree and Concentrates 62.2 la 72..1 2:2 821.2 12.2 AIL) 8.4 /la ??ia 61.2 O ...,i13Base Metals and Manufactures 8_212. 22.8 na 10.2 2.8.12 L2 68.3. Li 62.5 id ati CD -I 0 Ferrous Metals 26.3 4.1 27.3 3.6 6.8 0.9 19.2 2.2 7.6 0.7 12.8 a- Rolled Ferrous Metals - 4.7 0.6 2.1 0.3 8.3 0.9 0.3 neg3.. 4b. co > Non-Ferrous Metals 56.2 8.7 50.4 6.6 51.7 7.0 48.9 5.5 54.9 a Tin 47.9 7.4 32.4 4.2 45.5 6.2 39.3 4.5 41.7 a K.1 gebmaicala /.1 1.2 32:2, 3..../ 14.0 3.42 ma 2.0 a a -Wood and Wood Products a 0.4 liega. 22 neat .9A mfg. 1.0 c'Eriee footnote at end of table. -1 Total Imports a/ Killion US Value 848.1 gzi 0.1 5.0 48.9 3.8 34.8 Percent 0 190. a Percent Value P.Nc-ent 100.0 251:1. Li.1 rota. CD ? No. a a a 2 - 0.3 2.5 030.5 C)_ 742_ 143.11 1720.41 11 42-9 =It 1.5 817 21.6 a 5.8 34.2 cD6.2 4.1 22.4 24.1 (7) 6.6 cAS a c0.3. cr--- 1.0 13.:2 1.12. 0.1 1.0 0.1 Table 17 Commodity Composition of Soviet Imports from Communist China 1955-1961 )=. (continued) 73 73 .????=01M.abmgmess., (1) 955 1956 1957 1958 1959 < -11 9, '1 Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent .Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent ???????amosmasimmonimiNVIIM 1, Million US$ and Percent oflotal X a) c7Rubber and Rubber Products 21 0.1 22.,2 La zu 242. 28.1 la all 2.1 11.6 1.4 ilt c7;/43.6 0 CD Textile Raw Materials and a) K.) Semi-manufacturee 2212. 22 giL6., la LiItp. 6.6 MI ila %,.?. LA 041 Li g.,2 g?, 4.2 a m-.. C) aa Cotton - - - . 52.3 4.8 4.0 8.0 81.5 4b. Wool 2-3.6 3.7 23..4 ..8 23.9 3.2 21.2 2.4 21.9 2.0 131 2.3 10.4 s21.9 C) .Ph 31Consuner Goods 245.0 1111 316.5 41.4 294.8 1212 42111 VIA ftla 2822 516.9 61.2 46.1.2 0..:2 ill! Food 183.5 28.5 209.5 27.4 137.9 18.7 230.1 26.1 219.1 19.9 127.9 15.1 17.4 vg 33 Other Consumer Goods 61.5 9.6 107.0 14.0 156.9 21.3 251.2 28.5 424.0 38.5 389.0 45.9 343.8 0 33 TOtbar Merchandise 170'1- 26.4 190-21 Met 184.3 25.0 162.5 18.14 2.E12 121/ 21:1au -.1 (.0 -0 0.3. Legae Oil WA. 1.6 0.2 4.1 isti 1.3. o.6 16.8 2.0 Ra i'lli c;IUnspecified _% ..-40.--- li!il. Because of rounding, eoMP04#Pts may not add to the to as shown. U, C) > 4=k (I) a > a r..) a co a a r..) a co a a _% a a a _% a a a _% a . a CD 0- -11 0 (D-4ota1 ExportoaJ FIFFuelso Lubricants and Recn - a) lated MMterials CD K3 C) C) c) "Ores and Concentrates o4 0.0 Manganese Ore F.1 .33Ease Metals and Manufactures -0 CD a a 4=k CD a a Cr) Wood and Wood Products a a Lumber a Coal and Coke Petroleum and. Petroleum Products Ferrous Metals Pig Iron Rolled Ferrous Metais Non-rerrous Metals Tin Aluminum a a See footnote at end of a table. Table/8 Commodity Composition of Soviet Exportm to Industrial West 1955-1961 - iiliUSI.onandPercentfotz2. "0 lwr 1958 1959 1960 12?4.___ 0 Yalu? Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Peet a 21131 100.0 297.2, 100.0 690.1 100.0 669.6 100.0 8,5.5100.0 971.8 100.0 4,2g12,2 1.).0. _ x bla 85.1 (26.1 c) ibz2 7.7 1.4 16.2 2.7 21.7 3.1 16.2 2.4 14.6 1.7 14.9 1.5 13.3 41.3 gaa 1.?. 22A lla 1E12 16.4 22.:1, 14.2 A,..5_ 11.2 211.3 11.5 118.6 21,2 fr........ Ig:g z..11 2.9 11.7 65.8 ?..z 33.1 4.9 47.0 5.5 70.9 3:i 13,.g:8 ,T,7.6 .7 5.a 30.3 12.4 1.9 23.8 2.8 34.7 ....1.A -0-3 - 7.9 1.5 13.4 2.2 17.8 2.6 10.3 1.5 11.8 1.4 18.9 1.9 24.0 -42.3 CD -I 1.8 26.5 4.4 47.1 6.8 62.3 9.3 48.5 5.7 40.3 4.1 37.7 23.6 10.0 1.0 0.2 21.9 3.2 52.2 4.8 23.7' 2.8 13.1 1.3 1.8 c) .p.0.2 2.8 0.5 17.2 2.9 14.5 2.1 20.8 3.1 15.2 1.8 7.3 0.8 6.6 CD o.6 > a 32,a la,a 101.8 4312 145.3, 21.0 143.7 11,1 323,3 31115, 245.8 27.2 5.0 39.0 6.5 49.1 7.1 53.3 8.0 55.0 6.4 57.1 45.1 8.3 62.8 20.6 96.0 13.9 90.4 13.5 252.7 17.9 188.7 12.8 2.4 22.4 llt 28.6 4.1 31,2 Lk 311? 314 5.9 19.4 214.0 .324. 112.4 .221/ 95.3 16.0 14 16.8 152.9 18.4 _gm RA. Ina 1.8.2 73.2 ITV .1 Mk- -83=3 9.8 99.0 10.2 6 .1 -o -o 3 (I) Table 18 Commodity Composition of Soviet Exports to Industrial West 1955-1961 (continued) -a Milian US$ an4.,. Percent of 411 m 1959 1960 1961g ......2g.6___ jja.. ___ 2251._ 91 LL x value, Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value p_e_er2Lt (I) CT MTextile law Materi'als std 73 w cc, Semi-manufactures OA 12.0 5.8..4 2,12 42.0 6.1 32.ta I.L2 60.5. /41 72,1 :6,2 52.1 atz2 I?3 A) a Cotton Fibers 47.4 8.7 34.5 5.8 26.6 3.9 22.0 3.3 39.2 4.6 50.3 5.2 34.7 J,3 a a 8Consumer Goods 4=. al Food ? ? i Grain g.3 >4r 33? Other Consulter Goods o -o Furs and Pelts -.1 CL) -I Other Merchandise a a Unspecified 4b. CD ORR OA .12:8 70.0 12.9 47.5 8.8 37.8 7.0 35.6 6.6 68.4 12.6 52.14.212 MIS 2,2:1 135,2 aLjt 32V1 18.4 1:7ll7 20.3. 169.1 Mat Ella 77.4 1.3.0 96.3. 13.9 85.0 12.7 126.4 14.8 117.2 54.1 9.1 68.2 9.9 63.1 9.4 99.1 11.6 85?3 39.6 6.7 39.8 5.8 38.4 5.7 45.3 5.3 51.9 36.2 6.1 35.7 5.2 34.1 5.1 39.9 4.7 44.2 DA. ma f13.2. 12.0 21A 12:2 120.1 14.0 146.1 35.8 6.0 212, 12 g..?. 4.3. !1,./ -2:1 22:1 > a a. Because of rounding p components may not add to the totals shown. a I?3 0) a a a _% a a a _% 12.1 358.1 8.8 128.2 5.3 49.2 4.6 c) 4.5 41.4 3.9 1119. 228.4 *11 4.o 6.6 6.2 a- 1.- 1.000 1.0009ZOOV6P Table 1..9 Commodity Compos:i.ti= of Soviet Imports from the Industrial West 1955-1961 a rota ImPorts al c,PANachinery and EquixarAnt g Chemical Equipment a Transport Equipment 41=Base Icktals and Manufactures Co 33I -0 ^ Non-Ferrous Metals Copper co ?Wood and. Wood Products a Textile Raw Materials and > Semi -manufactures a a ? Wool Fibers a Synthetic Fibers a a 8 Consumer Goods a a 7' Other Werchandi_ge F Metals Roiled Ferrous Metals Pipes Unspecified Value 14307 3.81L5. 101.4 222.1 12.3 8.1 1.3 41.1 40.2 41.32.2 324.4 18.4 7.3 43.1 0.11.1?????????1.113,01.11.14 iEggs)AILL42y.d Percent of 1959 1960 Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent 100.0 Value 100.0 2788 100.0 67.2 100.0 622.2 100.0 756.5 100.0 1,0696 1,092.2 42.2 229.2 21143. 2.4a 194.1 221:2 22.1. 456.4 1s2a 474-4 0.3 .524? 0.1 7.4 1.1 19.5 3.1 77.8 10.3 135.4 12.7 131.9 23.5 145.7 25.2 97.3 14.5 76.7 12.3 91.6 12.1 121.1 11.3 66.1 12.4 gla 21.8 161.9 26.0 219.1 Els. im! 37,1 241.6 2.9 .12.0 74.0 12.8 _4111 104.2 15.5 106.3 17.1 175.9 23.3 252.1 23.6 186.5 1.9 65.9 11.4 88.8 13.2 97.6 15.7 94.4 12.5 135.7 12.7 96.5 0.3 2.6 0.4 5.3 0.8 1.1 0.2 68.9 9.1 101.9 9.5 80.8 9.5 9.3 49.1 45.9 8.542.1 7.9 40.5 6.3 6.o 55.6 54.1 8.9 8.7 43.3 35.7 5.7 4.7 45.1 38.2 4.2 3.6 55.3 32.0 11.4 ill 31..0 zit alt 10.2 il2.4 .?4.252.2.6.21 ?42 LS/ /IR 61.2 29.1/ 8.1 81-4 4.3 20.2 3.5 34.4 5.1 27.1 2.7 10.2 1.3 48.1 4.5 37.1 1.7 15.4 2.7 15.0 2.2 18.9 3.0 20.1 2.7 12.9 1.2 26.3 10.0 64.3 11.1 64.6 2. MI UAL ICU 1.1. 46.0 id 1315. ata 22.+, az2 10.1 /0.19 11.3 81111 111 115.2, 10.8 118.6 10.7 2L/ 1/1.11 Lk 10.6 AL/ 8.8 1.2 as 2.2 312 i;. Because of roundingo components may not add to the totals *Wm. 1961 Peilent 180.0 fe.1 at.8 5.1 tal K32.4 coo a 86.a. 0. ota ir 7-4,1 e s 200 4/ 1 49A002600010001-1 1 ; ; clt' 41 fl :IAD9 a :0;1 "671 a IiI c? II irg ciA LA 11 41 ill A (2 ct:11 el Z;i (AiI II i II 42' li 1 i i?,4 g i 1 il .6 0 1 2 1 .3 mi LI x 0 0 Lb .3 LI git, g. i I 'i I/ 11 11; 1 114 I ApproVed For R1eas1 2000/14/18-:itar-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 di1yCx:anyzit:Loa ,ftosiamemkarall?WOMICIP...aueligniNe,ernsimrweog (t, a_ Value Percent Value Percent 0 Xt? otal Imports el. Esa 100.0 ,e."6.,2 100.0 wA)Cotton 11L2 8.4 211 355 Niatura3. Rubber z:13. 28.0 a a Pood 103.4 !.?2.11 211 a e? on-Ferrous Metals 0.2 nes 2.1 0.6 Other Merchandise at6 Unspecified 20.0 12 a2.22 15.4 viet Imports 1955-196) te Italdert;e1,relc d > mr..1.,,,awmo.Nwormawommemmo?a?wavomm,,,,,am,002 ,,,,,,,fiammoomm,of MAI:Lan US r% ,rj, .., =1'4 0 I' tyl.....2..I ___1271._.. ____i___,..._ ........_ .A.A2. a Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Percent Value Pewent o ilaia 100.0 aii2 100.0 27/1 100.0 7-R42 100.0 2a2a ar2 co 122.6 21.2!,2 135.2 M...2t 311.6 12,12 139.4 Ais 122.0 FAI w .?.72? ati, 1.31.4 211 144.0 &49. 151.8 god 224.8 EtLs a INA za. 3.03.6 .1.2z5 115.0 20.0 232.4 31.8 403.2 stai 8 2.6 s.s.2 20.. La IA1 8.6 45.8 al 2...2 ...2. INA 26.6 kati nto 145.4 2s.....1 160.1 p_.1_,.2 ma. 136.i C) la, 8.8 La 2,/ La 2.4 21 21/L6. FL.9 -0a. Because of rounding, compon. add to the totale shown. ?-?1 C^ D 4=k a co 4b. > CD a > a a K.1 a o) K.1 a o) a 0 0 0 -% 0 0-% 0 0 0 0 -% 0 I -% I 1 ?-?1 OS Cil OS 111. a e aCtO a. 4.11 ?? Vem?CACIA.4.*04 es% rte0250:00 0 -1 Lmelow) Cu ON N. 0 t???? 4: I 0 Ert laRS N AA A CO .zt C-- CA CO Cr% for.14421Cggli..-C91 ? ? ? ? ? ? ? cu Cu curte-armoptoialtr% ? ? ? ? ? ? ? ? ? uCO c`fl gicRSY4 A ? ? ? 440;,....z 0 rree World-Total A one4cocotAnn-d- A t...c040%,^AvDco ? *?? ???? ? ? ?????? ? ?0 A3NRgIVMA MelgM-gR4' cum gig m3S4) 4 UtO, 43 $4.10W A4HAXAg 43 0112111i Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 SHISCIZD BIBLIOGRAPHY affat Allen, R. Soviet Beanpole Wartime (Public Affairs Press), 1960. AMbrey, H. Coexistence: Bcomomic Challenge and Response (National Planning Association), 1961. Berliner, J. S. Soviet Beanpole Aid: She New Aid and Trade Policy in Underdeveloped Countries, Praeger, 1958. Cho:al.:km, P. A. Organization and Techniques of Foreign Trude of USSR tTraoslated from Russian by joist Publication Research Service: 1863-N; COO 2657-N), Moscow, 1958. Goryumov, V. P., et al, eds. Foreign Trade of the USSR vith the Socialist Comatries (translated from the Russian by the joint Pdblications Research Service), JIGS No. 969.M, CSO No. 28911W1), October 1959. Rayner, M. The Challenge of Coexistence: A Study of Soviet NICOMOMIC Diplomacy (Pdblic Affairs Press), 1961. Mikeeell, R. and Behrman, J. Financing Free World Trade with Sino- Soviet Bloc (Princeton University Press), 1958. Rove, A. and Donnelly, D. Trade vith Communist Countries, Hutchinson, 196o. Spulber? N. The Beano/nice of Communist Baste= EUropes Wilay, 1957. U.S. Congress, joint Economic Committees 1959 (Comparison of the United States and Soviet Economies, Part I and II). U.S. Department of State, The Sino-Soviet Economic Offensive in Leos Developed Areas. Pdblications No. 66320 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIR-IMIS79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 U.S. Department of State, Commmnist Niemand* Policy In the Lees Developed Axton. Pablicatim No. MO. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Governmemt Printing Office, 1960. Waselaki, J. N. Commmnist Ecomomdc Strategy: The Bole afloat Central Europe (National Planning Association), 1959. Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Apprgtead For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Aysenberg, I. Novyy Valyutnyy Mars ROblya New ftehange Rate of the Buble)0 Noscov 1961. Frays L. I. Neshionarodnyye Raschety 1 FinansirovanlyeVissalsmsy Torgovli Sotsialistichetkikh Strum (International Settleseets and Financing of Forego Trade of the Socialist Countries), Rogow 1960. Crenbiz4 D. IL, ed., Pravovoye Regulirovanlye Vneshomyibrgavli SISSR (Legal Regulation of USSR Foreign Trade), Nbsoov 1961. Kovrianykh, N. F. and Stegenow, S. kt., eds., Vneshnygya Torgovlya Stria Harodnoy Dendkratii (Foreign Trade of the Feogle's Democracies), kbscov 1961. Lavrichenko, M. V., Ekononichelkoye Sotrudnichestvo SSW so Streamed Axil, Airlki, i Latinskoy Amaral (romoomic Cooperation of the USSR with the countries of Asia, Africa, and Latin America) Ministry ,of Foreign Trade, USSR %mamma Torgovlya la 1955-1959 godlri StatisticheskiySboraik (Foreign Trade of the USSR for 1955- 1959$ Statistical Handbook), Moscow 1961. Ministry of Foreign Trade USSR Vnesbnyaya Torgovlya se 1960 gods Statisticheakty Obzor (Foreign Trade of the USSR in 1960, Statis- tical Survey), Noscov 1961. Ministry of Foreign Trade USSR Vneehmaya Torgovlya ea 1961 mg, Statistichelkiy Obsor (Foreign Trade of the USSR in 1961, Statis- tical Survey), Nbscov, 1962. - 81 - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Semen?, S. D., Ekonomicheskoye Sotradalchestvo i Vaalmorpomosbeh, Siren Sotelelisticheskomo Lampe Otomaosic Cooperation and Mataal breistance of the Socialist Camp Countries), *meow 1959. Sladkowskly, M. I., Oche*" lkomomicheekikh Othoebmi S8R s Kitezrma (Outlines of the Economic Relations of the USSR with China), Moscow 1957, Selected James of the Soviet smartbly periodicals, _AfttgaVie la!an (Forego Trade)* Voteosy,Eknmonal (Prdblems or Economics)* Dwell I Kredit (Money end Credit)* aroma" Mammas 1 Mashdonarodnve Otmoshenlya Norld Moon/mar and Iwbmnmettomal Relations), and others as sell as the newspapers Pravda, Isvestiya* and Eki.j.oe.cgat.ftp_acheGasata. Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 :taL RECENT RECORD IN SOVIET ECONOMIC GROWTH CHAfTER N TRIMS IN MB FROWCTION OF CONSUMER GOODS 1 October 1962 .t3Y STATINTL Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79101049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 , COWEVIS . rnooavoaao o o 0 0. a 1 , 60 00060 060 ao.f.0000lLa; Co ? 99 Ca 5 0 0 0 0 41C, 0 dr ? 0 0 0 Knit outerwear 7.4 33 Oftit underwear 10.5 5.8 WHosiery a 8Leather footwear 5.9 CD C) C) Ma. Percentages were derived from data contained in the following sources: data for 1951, Promyshlennoste CD c) SSSR, Moscow, 1957, pp. 328, 343, 351; data for 1958-61, SSSR v tsifrakh v 1961 godu, Moscow, 1962, c) c) pp. 127, 128; percentages for Jan-Jnn 1962 were reported in Pravda, 23 Jul and data for the Seven Year Plan (1959-65), Pravda, 8 Feb 59. c) cib. Percentage increase over Jan-Jun 1961. c) ?c. Lower limit of the range. 101. Production was 96% of previous year. e. Production was 98% of previous period. Average Annual Increase 1952-1958 2.8 8.1 Annual Increase (Percent) Jan thru jun 122 1962 b/ 3;959-1965 7.1 4.8 0.7 2 4.2 2/ 7.4 7.7 5.6 3.9 3 dJ decrease 1.9 1.2 8 2/ 10.2 6.5 decrease decrease 6.9 7.4 5.2 6 9.8 7.7 3.3 6 4.3 4.1 3.7 9.4 7.5 5.5 4 8.4 4.0 7.4 10.0 5.6 5.4 Co 0 0 CD -1 a a .1)k CD Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 previously achieved in 19600 but the rate for light industry continued to decline. The 4 percent increase achieved during the first 6 month period of 1962 and the 5 percent achieved in 1961 are well below the 6 percent average increase needed to fulfill the Seven Year Plan, l!t/ and are far short of the 7 percent average annual increase achieved during the previous seven-year period, 1952-58.* A. !Mxtiles. Recent trends in Soviet output of textiles show that fabric production increased at the relatively high rates of 6 percent and 5 -Percent respectively during 1959 and 1960, but that the rate of growth dropped off sharply in 1961. increases in the production of fabric for recent years and that planned for 1965 can be seen in the following tabulation: Year 2/ Production of Fabrics Index (1958.1oo) (million square meters) 1955 5,402 93 1958 5,823 100 1959 6,178 106 1960 6,467 111 1961 6,505 112 1965 Plan 8,135 140 a. Figures are from Table 2. -e average-ennual rate of increase for the period 1952-58 was computed from an index of production of finished commodities and weighted by retail prices of 1955. The computed index is slightly lower than the official index of production which is a gross value index in factory prices. -9- Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049AR020 &tor jj de '1:12c cline in the rate or growth in the textile Ged ist'filage part to shortages of raw materials and to other in Lndustrv i'See Bectton ILp pa 16)0 The testae industry still oependent on supplies of agricultural raw materials even gh rellemicel fibers are increasing in the total supply. Shortfalls Pst-cultutral production of fibers are being felt by the industry, r ported by plant managers who complain of lagging supplies. 12/ 'Alle shortening of the workday from 8 to 7 hours apparently contributed e increasing strain on the LAillSt17 LA 1961. In addition to ,.oeae er?bie the textile industry is exhorted by planners, retailers, ce alike to broaden the assortment of goods and to raise qi01 quality, the accomplishment of which would tend to slow the rate growth of the industry but wouli increase the effectiveness of output in satisfying consumer lemand. flu=ing the period, 1950 through 1961, the total production ile fabrics in terms of square meters almost doubled, as Table 2. Moreover, markel shifts have occurred during this peviod in the distribution of textiles according to type, in part indx atioa of a broader assortment. Cotton fabric, which comprised 84 percent of production in 1950, declined in its share of total .!:dbric to 75 percent by 1961 because of gains in other fabrics, 7)articu1ar1y fabrics of rayon and synthetic fibers. Woolen and Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Tale 2 Soviet Production of Textile Fabrics for Selected Years 1/ 1950 through 1961 mad 1965 Pim milliaa_mare meters me. es.mrsp,T run M{iM'Aa'0%,i=.8m.,,IME`Ntt:R. ?9.1,..6,0,60,2/PO.AftWellsan.0.1.eate?VMSVIVIOCM.MOia*.MMer. eottom 2,885 Wool 197 Bayou., synthetic, and silk 106 Linea 260 1.448 .12/ 1955 2/ p58 2/ 1959 2/ 1.22 .41 1261 2/ 12221411 4,370 1,308 4,615 4,838 4,874 5,700 320 385 415 438 455 635 431 690 663 675 683 1,215 281 440 485 516 493 585 5.402 5.821 6.178 6.467 6.505 8.115 a. Production of fabrics iu 1950 and 1955 were converted fran linear to square meters using the following coefficients: cotton 0.74; wool 1.27, rayon, synthetic, and silk 04.82; and linen 0.92. These coefficients, derived from official data for 3.958 which were reported in both linear and square meters, in ElnE2ssatta,mystvo SSSR v 1952_4odu., p. 2450 do not account for possible changes in the widths Zeta:twice during the earlier period, but such changes if they occurred wore probably small. b. Warodapye_yhozywtvo SSSR 111.120 4odit.!? p. 321. c. 1E1K- d. SSSR v tsifran :y 12.61,1e1E, P. 127 WaVait",?Erviit ?1959. Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 JAnen fabrics made nominal gains .l. Table 2 shows the production of the major groups of textiles since 1950 and goals for the Seven Year Plan. I a both quantity and quality, the Soviet Uaion still has far to go to reach production levels of textiles in the United States. Total Soviet production of textiles (measured in square meters) in 1961 was only a little more than half the American volume**, a level that is nnt adeqaate to supply -- at anything approaching the censumption staadards of many Western countries -- the needs of a appulation more than 18 percent larger than that of the United States. Seale of the factors that contribute to the relatively poor qaality of Soviet textiles, cam be enumerated. Fabrics generally eve lighter in 'might and narrower than those produced in Western aountries. Thread counts are lower, and yarns receive less twist0 Th roes irregularities found in yarns and fabrics result from thc use of raw materials of low qaality and from a lack of precision A n the spinning and veaving processes. A group of US specialists Chexea ii the percentage distribution of fabrics according to type were aa follows (based an data in Table 2). Tape of Fabric Cotton Wool 1742,y031 p Synth tie I) end s lk 83.7 74.9 5.7 7.0 3.1 10.5 lJnen 7.5 7.6 la 1961 Soviet production of fabrics mum 6,505 million square aeters (See Table 2) whereas the ,US production easequivalent to 32,100 mil/ion sqpnre meters. 16./ - Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 viiPaavegs FaarM to& ?MASI PitaM citIg9 1419A44240 WA/ as follows: 17/ Mills are somewhat concerned about the quality of the raw cotton they get, but they have to use what is furnished and turn out as good a product in maximum quantity as they can. Since they have little, responsibility for the product after it leaves the plant, they have no strong incentive to be concerned about anything more thanemeetiug mWetun standards. C. ClealmAgd_Footwear Much greater amounts of clothiag and footwear have been reaching the Soviet consumer in recent years than in the earlier years of the poet-World War II period. The amount of sewn rnents distributed annually through the retail stores in 1960 had more than tripled the 1950 level e o alcoet 8o Percent above the 1955 1evel.Agalfw of fabrics, on the other hand, have increased such less rapidly -- only 31 percent since 1955 -- reflecting a trend away from home- sewing and in favor of factory-made clothing. Sales of these commodities in the state and cooperative stores in recent years were as follows: (million rubles) si 70/ hi hi Commodity 1222 .2.2a Sewn garments 2,172 3,939 Fabrics s/ 3,950 4,566 ......e.111.0?11111.1.1e101.161??? 4.2513 2.,L62 5,582 7,051 5,619 5,982 a. tiarstime)5140zyartv,0 sgpR,y1958 godp, me 724. For 1990 only, sewn garments Include fur goods. b. Bared!eye khonyeetvo SSSBJFJOZIodel?, p. 690. c. Most of the fabrics sold in retail stores probably are SOWS into clothing either at home or by private tailor/1 or seamstresses. * PiGductioi-liata for the garment industry is incomplete. When It is reported, production of sem garments is based on value added which excludes the cost of materials. Before 1959 sewn garments were reported as gross value of production. 18/ The data for retail sales provide a more continuous series which may be more meentheul for making compavisoae. Approved For Release 2000/04/183.PCIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 floiAet-made clothing is notoriously shoddy, reflecting the yiocie quality of materials and waft:unship and the inexperience of the Aes guats. Much of the factory-made clothing, according to trade ficials, is unsalable due to n/ow grade sewing, poor finishing, ard s mplified, old-fashioned, and unvaried styling . . . with ious defects". AV During a 9-month period in 1961, the Ministry ii Trade, REUSR, rejected ha percent of the production of the garment ludustry? reclassifying the goods as seconds. ?2,/ In the knitting rades? output of hosiery has doubled since 1950, and knit outerwear and underwear have increased even more rapidly, albeit over a latively amall base. (See Table 3) Although production of leather footwourbes more than doubled 1950, neither the quality of materials end workmanship nor tbe assortment have improved appreciably. In order to meet production quotas, footwear manufacturers produce somewhat standardized models :112, a narrow range of sizes as a means of achieving production goals. stomer complaints concern shortages of particular sizes and the generally cheap quality that means ultimately a lack of durability. As for materials, artificial suede and other simulated leathers which are used to extend the supplies of genuine leather are far less durable materials, although composition soles probably are an acceptable oubstitute for leather. A further lack of durability results from construction methods ; vt often either are outmoded or are geared to ximum outpat rather than to producing a high-quality product. -13- Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Table 3 Soviet Production of RbItted Garments and Leatbarrootwear Selected Years 1950-61 and 1965 Plan million amen or minion mire 1.11 W 1229, 1222 .120, 2.222 2,960 la; . Alsie sr.se.elore,gestalAWASNIMInical.26,..mer.10ra,wede.amer.,,....., Comm:witty Leather footwear 203 271 356 '390 419 442 515 Knit outerwear 47 85 97 104 112 117 160 &1t underwear 150 1 346 399 439 472 488 780 Hosiery 473 772 888 926 964 1,000 1,300 a. EETENInnoat' Ego, Moscow, 1957/ PT. 343, 351. b. SSSR v taifrakh v 12611Lodu, pp. 127, 128. c Pre?r?vda&eb 159 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 D? The production of consumer durables is increasing rapidly, heugh the output is still small for household appliances except Zor sewieg machines and radios. Hausehold refrigerators, meshing machines, and television gets which have come into production La large nuebers only since 19500 are scheduled for rapid increases im the Seven Year Plan (See Table 4). Many other appliances that are common in the US -- such as dishwashers, clothes dryers, and food reeer - are virtually enknown to the Soviet panc. atecks of household appliances by the end of the Seven :tear Plan in 1965, according to Soviet estimates, mill include 7.6 million_ refrigerators, 12.3 millioa sashing machines, and 40 million seeing machines. 21/ If these levels are reached by 1965, Soviet officials estimate that there will be one refrigerator for every five urban households, one washing machive for every three erten heumeholds, and one sewing meehine for every two households Chothurbaa and rural). Although this inventoey coapares unfavorably eith presemt US inventories, It approaehes the current level of availability of these appliances im the Mt and some of the other Buropean countries. ge/ Radios, because of their value as means oV propagaada dieseminatioa, enjoy a relatively ugh priority in coesumer production and are priced fairly cheaply. Stocks of radios, according to official Soviet estimates had grown by 1960 to a level which provided 48 sets per 100 families. Stocks of television sets provided only 10 per 100 families. 23/ Approved For For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Teble 4 Soviet Production of Consumer Durables Selected Years 1955-61 and 1965 Plan rrare 0..B.47.1.8V,R49.42.116...76.61611216.14.3110.41.0MMAII.,400.7. no. 1950 2221 2221 Sewing machines 502 1,611 2,686 Refrigerators Washing machines Radios Television sets 1.2 151 360 0.3 ti7 464 1,072 3,549 3,902 12 495 979 thousatwis W12.112/131 2/ 22226O 1 221 g a 20941 3,096 3,292 4,550 426 530 686 1,450 648 896 1,236 2,570 4,035 4,165 4,229 60000 1,277 1,726 1,949 3,300 nettesammems.,nactv...412.?....timia=--,. 0.106waraalleir...7.2use....almare ,acsoramon.roassuValUdicamts.a.aleXareVarvanr..vouweeamir..-? a' aE21M212-a2z b. SSSR tsifrakh v 1 a. liyia_vdt..7 FRE 1959. Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Although consumers in the USSR are anxious to own appliances aEd other durable goods, they usually must wait many months for delivery and are often dissatisfied when they finally obtain them. Few of these items would be salable in retail markets in the United States. Appliances on the whole are poorly designed, crudely built, and subject to breakdowns. Soviet refrigerators have a small amount of anably7; space in relation to their size and weight. The washing machines are simple in design usually with roller wringers operated by hand; some have motor driven centrifugal spinners; and a small part of the production have simple timing devices. Electric sewing machines have been so unreliable that many housewives are returning to treadle machines stile a good portion of the newer models rust in warehouses. EY Even in the urban areas the usefulness o' appliances is limited by the undependable nature of the Soviet supplies of electric power.* Both the availability and quality of Soviet appliances have been influenced adversely by the preoccupation of planners with heavy industry. Instead of plants which specialize in appliances, production has been relegated to subsidiary shops of plants that specialize in other types of machinery. Production is pimply organized, there is little coordination among producers, and inadequate * Problems oTrzatic flow of current and fluctuations in voltage which have been reported result ia part Sr= inadequate wiring and improper distribution of current. More than 800,000 voltage stabilizers for use in operating home appliances were bought during 1959 alone. g2/ Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 ,pocia]iz^tica has led to high eoses. Until these deficiencies are -,'tified. Soviet consumers will find that household appliances, on , whole, axe scarce, expensive, and of pcor quality. Curreat Growth Problems and Prospects Strains now being felt by the consumer industries apparently are esused by factors which are numerous and complex. The sharp decline the rates of growth of the textile, clothing, and footwear industries la 1961 coincided with the period following the shortening of the eerk day from 8 to 7 hours, but other factors including shortages of materials, ed failures in investment also contributed to the line. Jew great has been the effect relatively of each of these Actors canaot he determined, but collectively they are probably :i'6aponsible for the lower rate of growth. A- Materials Shortages i:Iroviding increasing quantities of raw materials is one of the factors limiting the groeth of light industrial production ent and ie. future years. JUdging from past experience in A;eeduction of textile fibers by Sovietagriculture, fulfillment of .? e in likely to fall short of tle Seven Year Plea goals. Moreover, rca if goals are reached the output of natural fibers will basely support the plaaned increase in textile fabrics . For example, the Se- - Tear Plan requires that production of cotton fabric increase at an ?10.1al rats W! 4,2 to 4.7 percent, whereas the plan for output of cotton ::lbers yew:area an increase of 3.8 to 4.9 percent. 2:6,/ Soviet planners do reconizo that Soviet agriculture can no longer, as it has in the Ft7st supply fibers in adequate quswitIties to support the planned Approved For For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 expansion of the textile production. Thus future goals for textiles are based on the assimption that rayon and synthetic fibers can be produced in quantities adequate to supply the requirements of the industry over and above that which agriculture can produce. Production of rayon and synthetic fibers is scheduled to grow at the rate of 22 percent annwelly during the Seven Year Plan. 37/ Wbolen plants in partivalskr are to rely on large quantities of synthetic fibers, and cotton mills are to use synthetic fibers suitable for blending. Production of agricultural textile fibers in recent years has been slowing down; plans frequently are underfulfilled, particularly in years of adverse weather conditions. The following tabulation of production of textile fibers shows the output of cotton in 1960 and 1961 Was lover than the level achieved in 1959; annual increases In wool have declined for the past three years; and produation of flax fiber: fluctuates from year to year. Year ..N.M?tl,MA thousand metric tons a Cotton Oinnedly Wool Igrase). Illivaltamt_hetic Flax fibers 1955 1,290 256 110 381 1958 1,450 322 166 438 1959 1,550 356 180 364 1960 1,430 357 211 425 1961 1,510 367 250 403 a. SSSR v tsifrakh, 1961,Nassim. to Converted from the weight of seed cotton at 33.3 percent Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Although no figures arc avilable currently on supplies of xtile fibers reaching the textile mills, shortages of raw materials reportedly are responsible for production failures in some areas in 1961 and 1962. Ey Evezt so, the 'USSR exports large amounts of cotton, mainly to the East European satellites, an export volume which varies between 20 and 25 percent of Soviet domestic production each year. Although increasing requirements at home appear to strain the ability of the USSR to continue such extensive export, these commitments appear fairly rigid as indicated by theemport pattern of the past 10 years. 22/ Cotton imports on the other hand have increased somewhat in response to growing demands of Soviet light industry, but exports still are far greater -- actually twice the size of imports in 1960. 19./ Wool is alao in short supply because of failures in domestic production. Soviet production of wool in 1960 and 1961 increased by 1 percent and 3 percent respectively, compared with an increase of 12 percent in 1959 (See tabulation above). The fulfillment of future goals for light industry thus depends in large part on a lagging agricultural sector for supplying increases in natural fibers and on a heavily burdened chemical industry for supplying rayon and synthetic fibers.* Should agriculture and the chemical industry fail to meet the requirements of light industry, the official * A sharp ialetion in the growth rate for rayon and synthetic fibers was announced for 1962 -- from 20 percent implied by the Seven Year Plan to 12 percent. 31/ Approved For For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 prograa for increasing the supplies of textiles and clothing to Soviet consumers would be placed in serious jeopardy. In this event, Soviet planners would have to look abroad for large quantities of textile fibers with which to supplement domestic supplies. B. hew Level of Tedtmtlegx The low level of technology which characterizes much of Soviet light industry can be attributed in large part to the fact that, in the allocation of investment funds and resources, light industry has been given a low priority. The Seven Year Plan prdvided some improvement in the allocation of funds for light industry relative to other main branches of industry (See III C below), yet this higher level of investment apparently is not great enough to constitute a significant rise on the priority scale. Allocations of funds for the Seven Tear Plan period and the preceeding 7-year period for the light and food industries are compared with allocations for other selected industries as follows: 1959-1965 2/ 1952-195812/ 1959-1965 IV in percent of Branch of Industry (billion rubles), rubles,'201:1).2,9_5 Light and food 4.o 8.0-8.5 200-212 Machine building 6.6 11.8 180 Ferrous metallurgy 4.1 10.0 245 Oil and gas 7.2 17.O-17.3 235-240 a. DS Joint Publications Research Service: TS: 14,600 Ca ital Construction: A Statistical Collection, 26 Jul 1962, p. 18. b. In pricesof 1 NI 1955 adjusted to the new 1961 rate of exchange. l9 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Thus, the share in investments of the light and food industries (representing personal consumption) is less for both the 7-year periods than the shares respectively of the machine building, ferrous metallurgical, and oil and gas industries, and the increase in the Seven Tear Plan for the light and food industries is less than that in two of the heavy industries enumerated. Because light industry has been starved for resources over the years, technological improvements have been slow to develop and as a result, labor is used extensively, including much hand labor. The number of industrial workers in Soviet light industry, ranks high in the total of industrial workers for all of Soviet industry, being exceeded only by the number of workers in the machine building and metalworking industry. Of the 18.6 million Drpitiveumwwc.s.....1 capAlg46 in Soviet industry in 19600 light industry employed 3.4 million or 18 percent. 2/ Even lv the textile industry, which is more advanced in the mechanization of processes than are the clothing and footwear industries, much '...arger numbers of workers on the whole are used for given operations than in US textile industry. The size of the industrial labor force for textiles in the USSR is far greater than that of the VS textile industry, but the Soviet output of textiles is only about half as great. Ratios for the two , pronmeuenuorkers (rabochiy) employed in Soviet light industry in recent years were as follows: (thousands) 1955 2,158 1958 2,515 1959 2,579 1960 3,311 The increase of 792,000 workers in 1960 over 1959 reflects mainly the integration of the producer cooperatives into the state industrial system. Source: ly(1?2gsole khousyEtvo 126.0.1edu, p. 217. Approved For Release 2000/04/18,0ccIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 countries have been reported by the Soviet writer, S. A. Kheynman, for cotton fabric in 1958 showing Soviet production at 56 percent of US productioa,Aut the Soviet labor force reportedly was 87 percent greater than its US counterpart. 3y Measurements of labor productivity in the various branches of light industry are difficult to make because of the lack of data; figures on the Soviet industrial labor force, in particular, axe scarce. However, some comparative research in labor productivity has been made by both Soviet and US writers. A comparison of the productivity of labor in the USSR and the US has been made by the Soviet writer, A. Eats, which shows that the Soviet output per production worker in the textile and footwear industries, ranged from 38 to 44 percent of output per production worker in the US, when comparing US ratios for 1956 with Soviet ratios for 1957. Data from the Kate study are as follows: Branch of Isch9lEx ei Unit of Measure 22101 .per Worker us USSR USSR in percent Sl956) (1957).. of US Cotton fabric linear meters 20,052 7,712 38.5 Fabrics of rayon, synthetic fiber, and silk linear meters 19,668 7,512 11/ 41.5 Wool fabric linear meters 3,411 1,443 42.3 Footwear pairs 2,527 1,112 44.0 a. V. A. Zhamina, Edr., Ekonomicheskoye sotsializma c 1962, p. 200. b. As reported in the source. Using the data for output per uothor as presented in the source actually yields 38.2 percent. Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 The ratios obtained by Kats, however, are high when compared with results obtained by Western researchers. To the advantage of Soviet statistics, the Kate ratios are based on output offabric in linear meters which ignore the fact that the VS fabrics are wider than Soviet fabrics in all cases. Thus, comparatively, the US output per production worker is understated for each of the various fabrics. The measurements made by Gertrude Schroeder for 1956* based on output of fabrics in square meters shove Soviet output per worker much lower then the Kits figures. For example, the Schroeder comparisons show Soviet output of cotton fabric per worker to be as low as 23 percent of the US output as againut 38 percent derived by Kilts. Similarly, the ratio for mom, synthetic, and silk fabrics vas 27 percent compared with 42 percent derived by Kats. In opite of the wide variation, however, the low output per Soviet worker shown by both of these measurements, reflects the large inputs of labor and the relatively low level of technology of Soviet light industry. * The output per production vorker in the USSR and the US vere reported as follows: (1956) Ratio Commodity Unit USSR (USe100) Cotton fabric square meters 24,838 5,798 23 Rayon, synthetic and silk fabric square meters 22,524 6,164 27 Wool fabric .square meters 4,377 1,815 41 Footvear (except rubber) pairs 2,672 1,046 39 Source: Gertrude Schroeder, "Sem Measurement Problems in Comparing U.S. and USSR industrial Labor Productivity". eaper presented at the International Conference on Labor Productivity, Lake Como, Italy, 1961. -22- Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Aacognieing the general backmardness of their consumer utrie, Soviet officials aspire to emulate the technological level or the more advanced consemer industries abroad, mainly that in the United States. Procurement of textile plants and machinery from 14i/2e-tarn eeeefacturers plays a major role In expending the capacity f the Soviet consumer industry, particularly the textile industry, and has the added advantage of contributing to the technological advanceaent of the tadustry as well. Furthermore, the purchase of mechinerv abroad lessens the preesure on the machine building plants at Italia end at the same time saves costly reseerch and designing time 'byemaking possible the outright copying of the mcst advanced exedeas pranced by Western industry. Mthough Soviet purchasing officials have Indicated a strong leterest ia and preference for US textile processes, mainly those uelmg synthetic fibers, they also are purchasing textile machinery fran firms in West Germany, the UK, Italy, and Japan, in addition to that imnorted free the East European satellites. Imports of machinery for light industry, largely textile machinery and eqpipment? has iecreased rapidly in recent yearn, the total in 1961 reaching 57 million elhlea as compared with 20 million rubles in 1958. W By contrast, the tBSE?appeare generally less interested in importing technology end equipment for other breaches of light Industry, such as the garment keiteear? and footwear braachee that in general are even more beekvard than is the textile traneh. Plaened Improvement in the teChnology for light industry thus is centered primarily in the epleming and weaving of textiles. Approved For Release 2000/04/18 ?tIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 0, fnvestmeut of Capital Plans and Performance , _ _ _ ? _ ? Lerner amounts of investment ftlas have been allocated to Soviet light industry for the construction of new plants, the expansion of existing plants, and for is and re-equipment than have been, invested during earlier plans. Investment in state- owned enterprises of light industry, as originally announced in the Seven Year Plan, totaled 3.3 billion rubles* or 2.6 times the investment of the preceding 7-year plan (See Table 5). Still this allocation of funds apparently was not sufficient to support the expansion progran scheduled for light industry. In 1960 Khrushchev called billion for additional investment funds of 2.5/to 3.0 billion rubles to be allocated. not to light industry alone, but "for the development of the textile and footwear industries, (and) their bases for raw materials and machinery construction . . ." .g/ The division of this investment atong the various industries -- light industry, agriculture, and the chemical and machine buJIAIng Industries -- was not announced but directly or indirectly, light industry will profit from all these investments. In Doric of 1 ally 1955 adjusted to the trey 1961 rate of excbanao. 'Tne producer cooperatives were still operating outside of state industry when the Seven Year Plan began and thus their investment plans are ant reflected in the original plans for investment in light industry. By the end of 1960, the cooperatives had been integrated into the state system presumably adding their onsIl share of funds to the investment t:ands allotted to light Industry. .56/ Approved For For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Table 5 Capital Investment in Soviet Light Industry .9;14 1$.n.1.0.1`05, Million ni Mewed Investment Ratio of Planned Investment 1959-65 to Actual Investment ,Ikiblee Actual Investment _Mtg..- 1959-65 1952-58 'fetal light Industry I)/ 1,260 3,300 ,51 2.6 to 1 Text13.es rii 900 2,500 2.8 to 3. Cotten 385 780 2.0 to 1 awn, evnitnalti and silk 74 710 9.6 to 1 Wool 3.33. 385 2.9 to 1 Other 'textiles sil 310 625 2.0 to 1 Enitwear and hosiery Li/ 53 185 3.5 to 1 8121A magnesite Si 89 178 2.0 to 1 Leather footwear It/ 218 437 2.0 to 1 a. In prices or 1 July 1955 adjusted to the new 1961 rate at exchange. b. Teketlyriart...Emplillsontosty no 3., 1959, p 9. ko originally armounced. Investment subsequently has been increased0 d. str.oiteltstvo, no 9, 1959, pp. 2, 3. e. ReaMuni. fc Estimte baze.d.o inforaaticei contained in shveypalia przgyshlissnost jp no 6, 1959, p. 3. Approved For For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 The 1961 investment plan 'which provided the spectacular tnerease of 54 percent (reflecting both the new allocations of funds and the trannfer of investments from the cooperatives) vas under- ruifilied, according to official reports, and an increase of only 18 percent achieved over the previous year. The plenned increase of 33.5 percent for 1962 17/ does not appear to be especially high considering the need to make up for the investment failures in /961. Because of failures in bringing new plants into production on schedmle, a re-evaluation of the construction program as early as aas undertaken/ 1960. The nunber of new textile plants scheduled for conntruction were reduced and emphasis shifted to the expansion of existing plants and to modernization of machinery anl production processes no For example, nyw textile plants originally planned for construction in 1960 were reduced from 36 to only 15. 1?/ The rising cost of expanding the capacity for production is most pronounced in the construction of complete new plants (as opposed to modernization) where the costs of building and ancillary facilities are added to those of machinery and eqpipment. 241,-Ftial-%,cPRt?PF-FIMRP,P= According to official planning figures, light industry is becoming more cepital-intensive. A reflection or the cost of expanding the industry is seen in a shift in the marginal capital- output ratio. For the Seven Year Plan in relation to the preceding * Induntry officials note that reconstruction of plants in light industry takes one-fourth to one third the investment of capital as . does the conntruction of new plantn ;. for equivalent increases in output. 32/ -2 5'. Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 7-year period, the marginal capital-output ratio, derived fran Soviet over-all plans for light industry is calculated from official data as 0.40 in contrast to 0.16 for the earlier period, as shown in the following tabulation: a/ E/ Increments to Production Capital Investment 2/ Period _SEillion RdastALL (Billion Rubles b/) Ratio 1952-58 7.64 1.26 o.16 1959-65 (planned) 8.33 3.30 o.4o .901.1.10311,441111.60110. 1111,01..*11.111., WM.-TM a. Tekstil'unITLyalstqlennostl, No. 1, Jan 1959, pp. 2, 3. b. In prices of 1 July 1955adjumbadto the new 1961 rate of exchange. c. Derived. Although the ratio for light industry as a:whole for the Seven Ter Plan is more than double that for the earlier period, ratios for individual commodities would probably vary considerably. For example, in cotton textile production the change would probably not be as great as in anew and expanding area such as the processing of synthetic fiber into yarns, knitgoods, and fabrics. Thus, the relatively high ratio of capital to output reflects the changing technology in textile processes, the substitution of capital for labor, and, in part, the lag between new investment and the resulting gain La output, rather than a definite decline in the marginal productivity of capital. In this branch of industry, major increments to production may be forthcoming in subsequent periods beyond the Seven Year Plan, Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Plapving,and_Administrative Weaknesses Centralized planning for consumer needs, as it exists in the LOSR, has been established in a clImate of scarcity; whether such planning can work efficiently where the supply of goods permits a greater degree of consumer choice is yet to be proven. So far there is little evidence that Soviet planning can cope effectively with the problems of growing consumer requirements without broad revisions of present practices in production and supply. Iaventories of consumer goods at the production plants and in the trade network have increased rapidly, almost doubling in the period 19554960. Stocks of wool fabric, sewn garments, and leather a footwear have grow tiparticularly rapid rate during this period, although stocks of cotton fabric have grown very little, a development which suggests that cotton may be more acceptable in quality or price, or 'both, tham some of the other commodities. The following tabulation shows the growth of stocks in wholesale Us& organizations ayAd in industry for important consumer 125.2 items in recent years: (in mAllion rubles) Commoaitx sit Cotton fabric 271 267 282 Wool fabric 151 185 289 Silk fabric 154 223 274 Sewn goods 84 155 324 Leather footwear 96 106 214 !arodoye khozyaystvo v SSSR v 1960 odu, p. 699. Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Although recent organizational changes in planning and tration of light industry have improved its operation, many problems remain. Through the decentralization of Soviet industry in 1957, the pinioning functions of the Ministry of Trade for light industry vere transferred chiefly to union and republic planning bodies gospnans)*Itebile the regional sovnarkhozes took over the administration of the industry and assumed only limited planning functions. itil/ Later, in 1960, the producer cooperatives (collective groups of artisans and handicrafters) operating outside of state industry were placed under the administration of the local sovnarkhozes, a move which further increased state control over consumer production.121/ Such administrative changes, while improving the direction of the industry added other problems, particularly in coordination. Production goals and allocations of materials, in large part, are controlled at union and republic levels, whereas the administration and management are mainly the responsibility of the sovnarkhozea. In practice, plant managers claim, the USSR Gosplan sets up the aggregate goals for production taking no account of the increased cost of changing the assortment, such as providing more working cepitel,ldbor, n&,. the like. Thus, plant manna= An 11123, the assortment in response to orders from the trade organizations may run the risk of failing to meet over-all plan goals. Because of ------ Exceit for long-term planning which in April 1960 was transferred from Gosplan, USSR, tothe State Scientific Economic Council (Gosekanomovet), USSR. 42/ Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 this, plauts tend to narrow rather than to broaden the assortment of goods produced. The distribution system for consumer goods in the USSR is notoriously inefficient because of the inadequacy of fends, lack of modern merchandising eqpipment, and because of organizational 'weaknesses. Consumers are accustomed, but not necessarily reconciled, to alternating gluts and scarcities of goods. In recent years a weber of changes have been introduced in planning and administration, particularly in the state trade system, in order to meet more effectively the requirements of consumers. eiece 1957, details of assortment, design, and quality have been worked out by sovnarkhoz officials, and factory managers, workeeg with the trade representatives. y.,1/ Orders for goods by wholesale and. retail organizations on contract include detailed specifications as to the kinds of goods and the delivery dates. While individual store ma era have thus gained some voice in determining the kinds of goods they will carry on their shelves, strict obseryeece of contract terms often_ increases the burden of tho produeors. 'While the assortment of goods is planned regionally or Locally, the aggregate goals and the allocations of materials to be used are planned centrally. Plant nanagers, thus are obliged to meet output levels set by Goeplan (with :penalties for failure) while at the working level they are at the mercy of the trading organizations who pleee orders, but who also can :the:we these orders according to Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 ueed, and ultimately to reject the goods if they fail to meet specifications. yil Such a multiplicity of organizational authority -- interdependent, over-lapping, and tangled in detail -- presents a range of problems of coordinatica which planners have been unable to solve in the past and which may be expected to increase in intensity as the assortment of commodities expands. -30- Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18: CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 leading e V8611, witch now ranks c?s efworld power, the consumers share the tfftal product of industry is still too small to satisfy their ic requ ements, in spite of the gradual rise in the level of lAving that has been achieved, line.er the existing system of o-kities for investment funds and other resources since 1950, light bas grown more slowly then total industry and slower still cexigmrnd with 'Cue machine building branch of heavy industry. Nevertheless, by 1960: light industrial production had grown to 2.5 times the level 1950, almost doubling the output of textiles, more than doubling ieAe output of leather footwear and hosiery, and increasing at an even faeter rate the output of kmitwear and sewn garments. Still these ewaa far from adequate when measured either by consumer g_atisfaction or by the official standards for optimum consumption. Peesently light industry, growing at a rate below that needed to reach the 1965 goal, is producing half the textiles and only a tittle more then half of leether footwear needed to reach the norms vhich Khrushchev has pledged to achieve by 197o., Even the production required by the Seven Year Plan, should it be reached, is still far ohort of supplying the prescribed norms as shown by the following data per capita. k961 Te..mttles (square meters) 29.9 Leather footwear (pairs) 4.965Jsm 35.2 2e0 2.2 ...Cs.na_iti_oit_ual Nora 58.1 3.5 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Tor apparel Soviet coasumers are receiving much more factory- ?tiling them ahey did in earlier years. Retail salts of sewn almost 80 percent above 1960 mc2e / the 1955 level, mhereas, sales of fabrics ferg1t70;-14 e- period increased only 30 percent, indicating that as the of factoryenade clothiag increases, the need for sewing at heae aed by private seamstresses and tailors is diminishing eieles the radios ard sewing mecines which are fairly common out the USSR, many urban householders in recent years have eenuired their oen television sets, refrigerators, at washing machines. aeaever, the appliances are of poor design, by quality of construction, ee - undependable operatioa to the exteat that many of then would not be salable in Weatern markets.. By 1965 Soviet officie]s estimate households et for each 5 urban / ehere will be one refrigerator; for each 3 urban households, one mashing machine; and of all Soviet houneholds, uetaa and rural, half will have sewing machines. Few alants -pzciaLize in household appliances, production being relegated dtead to subsidiary shops of machine buildirg plants that specialize other types of achiaery. Soviet 11ahe industry recently has suffered a decline in rate of eeowth, falling from an increase of 9 percent In 1959 to an increase ok 4 percent during the first 6 months of 1962 over the corresponding aeriod in 1961. The preseat rate of growth thue is below the 6 percent average annual iacrease required to meet the 1965 goal and is also below the 7 percent achieved annually in the preceeding 7-year period. Cortributing heavily to the decline in rate of growth are shortages of raw materials aad failures im achieving the investaent plans. Approved For Release 2000/04/18 :-&-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 ,q0vte sgrj.culturc mew be uaaale mdeepately to meet the tz of Uo textile inaostrv ia the future Is a probability rL 7 pixnaiv4g ofYJefi_alt appareatly accept. The output of agricultural ff,:bera recently has inoraased et a decliming rate, increases for both cotton &Ed wool falling in 1960 and 1961 far below the increase acal;?eved In 1959. Light industry thua must rely more heavily on the oonaagricaltural types of textile fibers -- rayon and the various tyoes of synthetic fibers which are now being developed. The low technological level at which Soviet light industry operates is reflected by high inputs of labor and a relative la lov Jawastment of capital. Light ledultry's share of investmaat, even 7dlem coMbined with the food industrools still below the-,%-ATCS respectively of the maclOsae buildtag, ferrous aaaallurgicalo and oil e.viV1 gas iRdustries for both the Seven Year Plao and the 7-year period aroceedtao it. Because of its techno:agical lag, the Soviet liabt ?Joalustry compares poorly wIth that the US, the annual output per Soviet production amountine to lem than balf of that of his U6 .counterpart. .1') help in raiaing the level cf techuology, the USSR is importing modem machinery and Piquipmitnt frali 11.11/8L Western countries -- mainly the US, the UK, West Germ", and others as well as fraa the Fast European satellites. On balance, the Soviet consumers' lot hso improved gradually over time, but the prospects are that future gains &Liao vill be gradual in spite of the growing desires of connumera for more and lietter goods. Soviet light industry, which continues to build gradually oa Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 heverats of pis' veers, is becoming increasingly burdened with woblems of expansion. TO increase the capacity for production and to aviae enough raw materials to support it, is the tlsk of the -ecent and of the future. Irr Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved ForRelease2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 JIVIA ! )0 o Mogcow. 14'; Oc.Wber 1959 10 Deceffber 1959. rravda. 9 Auguat 1960, .r.loted in the New.York_Time, 21 ne 1961, 'A'Ommunist. No. I, 1961, -r:f 6, TekGtiL1nava promvithlennost' No. 10, 1960, p, 1. 7 Trud i zarabotnaya plata, No. 1, 19591 pp. 9-16, ..._ _ 11 ftavda, 1 Jun 1962 and Pravda, 25 Sap 1962. _ . 9, Pravda, 19 Uetober 1961, 1,(L Pravda, 6 My 1460., Planovoye khozveyetvo. No, 6. 1965, pp 51-63. 12, Tovarovedeniye promyahInnirkh i nrodovol'etvennykb tovarov, MORcow, ,.rp Y. ? ? 1955 Pp- 368-174 anct U. S, Eureau of Census, Facts forinduatry, ? ? __? "Woolpm and Wortd Woven Goods". M22T. 3-1-8 Supplenwnt, .3 4arch 1959, :vestlya, 14 October 1960. 11, Pravda, 8 )br-Ilerv 1959 5kst11'neya nromytihlennoa',o 12, 1961. pp. 1-4. 16. 1? S. Bureau of (encu, Stat1-;ticE,1 Abstract of t13.1. United States. 1.962, p. 797, 17. 14. S. Departmnt of Agricultuy,e, Foreign Agricultural Service, totton in the Sovfat Union. ;1"un 1959; p. 10, _ Sovetqkw _torgoviya, Februar7 1960, p. 26, 19, Sovetskaya torgovly.a" March 1962 p, pp. 10-13, Pi. Planovoye khov,ve.y!'Atvo. No< 12, 1.9s9, p, 23, 22, U. S, rlepartmert of Commerce. "Pu;'dn'l and Defews Services kdmini)14tration) M. HouReholci. Appliances,, September 060, p. 105. Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : 61A-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 Approved ForRelease2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1 T,CPrgaTTIY.1 ? 4o, 1I 1961. ? 44. _ torgovlyA, 30 January 1962. 27 May 1960. - _Pravda. 8 14'.,bruary 959.1. 9'eksti1Enava promvIsleancat'. Bo. 12, 1961, pp. 14.- 1S Joint Publications Reearch Service: 4IES/7JC-349 Voreignyrade of _the USSR, 1956, 4 november 1958, pp. 22, 40, 3EMS 526-D, Foraiga7rade.or theUSSR,_1958, 17 February 1959, pp. 21 , 37 11-.1S 6220 Ieoreign Trade_of 1 bf.i_USSR,_1959, 14 november 1960, pp. 24, 41. H349 Foreign 7-C-rad4. of the USSR. 1960, 5 April 1962, pp, 27, 49. )Lbid, 3A, PrRviia. 8 February 1959. 32, Narodnoye khozvaystvo y 1960. godu, t, 217. SO A. Cmgaulastslya poilmodetva prOikvod?t1 ai?ttruda, 31n,?,shnays. torgovlya soyuza SSE za 1959 god, passim. bay tnr,croviwi, fAnyuza SSR za 1960 god, passim, Tekstil'naya promyRnilunost' no, 10, 1960, p. 1. SSSR v tsifrakh v 1)60 godu, Pt =;10 312. Pravda, 7 December 1961, Ekonomika strciteltatva. 1950p 13 9 39 Flanovoye khozyaystvo, No. 5, 1957, p. 1. 40. Ekonomika stroitelsirva, No, 1.1, 1960, 1, 13. 41. SSSR v tsifrak v 1950 aodu. VDo 310, 312o . . " 2. Planovoye khozvaystvo No, 1, 1960, p. 91. k3, Pravda, 28 Novimber 1958. _ _ 44. Ibid., Approved For Release 2000/04/18 : CIA-RDP79T01049A002600010001-1