ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTS IN SOVIET ZONE GERMANY

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060110-1
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
R
Document Page Count: 
13
Document Creation Date: 
December 22, 2016
Document Release Date: 
October 5, 2011
Sequence Number: 
110
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
May 2, 1952
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060110-1.pdf613.42 KB
Body: 
Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP8O-OO8O9AOOO7OOO6O11O-1 CLASSIFICATIO "? ~"-'RICTF~ CENTRALS II ENOE~AGEN y INFORMATION FROM FOREIGN DOCUMENTS OR RADIO BROAD^ASTS COUNTRY Garman' Denoaratic Republic Lr SUBJtCT Economic - 1(aapower, agriculture, industry HOW PUBLISHED Pamphlet WHERE PUBLISHED Hoorn DATE PU9LISHED 1951 LANGUAGE German nn a wean wnuea nrosaawe amrnw nor unau span er nor ams nano mue nor euow or unosua an ro s. s. e.. a au u. u aeons. m nasanNOe a nor aauunos er m wsnen n an coca n u ausreoems news n ran cams n ur. urseNrnoe or nu rose u roee~rm. REPORT CD H0. DATE OF CATE DIST. .L /11~ 1952 N0. OF PAGES 13 SUPPLEMENT TO REPORT N0. Die Wirtschaftestruktur der Sow~etzone and ihre gegenwaertigen sozisl una_wirtschaftsrechtlichea Tendenzen. ECOAOHLC DEYE7APM6liPB SN SOVIET ZORE GERMANY Figures and tables referred to are appended Structural Changes is Soviet, Zone Germany Order the Nazi regime, the Soviet ~oae area increased its share in total German industrial Production from about 25 to about 26 percent during the re- armament period and maintained that level to the end of the war. In contrast, however, the present production of essential basic materials as opposed to industrial production in the Soviet Zone area accounts for only the following percentages of total German production: coal, 2.3; crude iron, 1.3; crude steel, 6.6; sulfuric acid, 20.0; lumber, 22.1; cellulose, 17.1; cement, 14.4. The productiott of these basic materials, which since 1945 represent a definite bottJ~aeck in the East German economy, cannot be appreciably increased in the Cen~.al German area. The Soviet Zone's dependence on raw materiels from outside is inherent. That is why the Soviet Zoae is so interested in interzonal trade, particularl,}. is coal and steel. Structurally, .the Soviet Zone ie a natural complement to the vest German econaagy, but the Soviets are attempting to eliminate ;,hie economic interdepeadeace by iacorpo^ating the Central German area into the greater Soviet economy. h The rigidity of the Soviet planning system and the brutal insistence oa P~ fulfillment have from the beginning limited the flexibility of the Soviet Zone economy. Furthermore, the ine]asticity of the reparation deliveries has increased the zone's sensitivity to crises. Production has been retarded by experiments with economic planning and by the Sovietization of the economy, but, since reparation shipments must be made regardless of the level of pro- duction, it has been the civilise sector of the'populatioa that has suffered. The c:.andard of living in the Soviet Zone has for years been very low, and SPATE AgNY DISTRIBUTION Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP8O-OO8O9AOOO7OOO6O11O-1 STAT Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060110-1 every new interruption of production caussa new and pnlnn,'+ gape in th? supply, A Px'eaeture and comZilete incorporation of the Soviet Zoae into the planned economy of the Eastern Bloc would have disturbed Soviet planning, Therefore,. the Soviets preferred to let the civil Population suffer, In contrast to the US, which is providing aid for West 0ermany, the Soviet occupation authorities have refused to alleviate the suppl,}. a-ficiencies, which are caused precisely by their reparation demands.(aee Table 1). III the 4 Years since the conclusion of land reform and the first wave oi' expropriations in industry and trade, the number of independent workers has dropped at'leas+ @00,000, The number of family members resisting such in- dependent w~rkera hen decreased by almost 500,000. Bet ore tLe waz, wage earners and salaried employees made up about 75 percent of all the vorkexs ir. the Soviet Zone area; the figure is pox 79 pex?cent, and the Five-Year plan sets 90 percent as the goal for 1955? Sovie? Zone Manpower Balance (see Tables 2, s, 4) In 1939, there were 15.2 mill~.on people in the present So?,iet Zone. area, x~ich comprises somewhat less than one fourth of the total wren cf the Weimar Republic. before the xar, the German regicn east, of thr. Oder-ileisse, actually larger than the Soviet Zone, had 9.6 million inhabitants, many of whom are now in the ~aviet Zone sa refugees. By the end of 1946 the population in the Soviet Zoae had increased by more the 2 million. Ir Land Sachae+, the numbers remained about the same, but is Thueringen, Sachsen-Anhalt, and western Brandentxrg, th~_ density cf population increased 20 percent, and in Mecklenburg owe; 50 percent. Although the few official population ?igures which the Soviet Zone has made public arc: contradictory, as a result either of inaccurate statistical methods or of deliberate intent to deceive, those available make it possible for us to reconstruct the manpower potential at the zone+e disposal, Ac- cording to the 1946 census, the social atruct,xre of the zone before the cur- rency reform xas less favorable than font of West Gex?many, and it cani:ot ilavr improved very much since teen. Iu both parL:s of Germany, the returnees have probably improved the demo ra hie com ositi~,n of the creased the labor potentis~. pThe accent p?pulation and have in- tone, considerab p ~? ~'= women employed in the Soviet ly above the percentage in West Germany, must have remair.~a about the same, rzrticularly since the atr~an: ei political refuga. from the ;:astern 7,cne into Nest German}? consists principally oi' men, and their departure must intensify the shortage of skit corkers. Before the xar, active workers made up r:ore than half the total population is both Central and West Germanf. It iG.a natural result of tYe heavy losses during the xar, which affected particularly +:he mast rroductive age groups, that the proportioex oi' active workers is now censiderably cmallE:. In the Soviet Zone, the number of workers is today about 7,7 million, the same as in 1939, although the number of people to be provided for bas increased by mil- lions. In both East and West Germany, the number of pars loners an3 ueople oa relief has increased considerably over the number 1n the prewar perio3. The workers in the Soviet Zone have to provide not on]y for themselves and for the large number of their own people xho cannot work, but rise for the Soviet occupation forces, who are obi?ged to live of.Y the ].and, ibis fact, and the low productivity, are the reasons why the Five-Year plan require: Y higher number oY productive workers to imprc+ve the numerical relationship betxeea xorkers and those provided for. The Five-year Plan requires an in- crease of about n million new xorkers, who, to a large extent, would have to `~ drawn from the reservoir of unemployed women. STAT Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060110-1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060110-1 Thus, the social tendencies of the labor policy pursued in the S:rvi~*. Zone are clearly recognizable: increasing numbers of independent workers are to become wage earners and hous;~vivee are to be drawn into industry, so that the inadequate technical productivity can be offset by a mass commitment of xorkers. The Five-Year Plan expressly demands that the percentage of women workers be increased from 37 to 42 percent of the total number of workers. Before the war, the percentage oY female wage earners in the Soviet Zone was under 3^c per- cent; even iactuding working housewives and independent workers, the total did not reach 37 percent. The planned increase in the number of xomen workers in the Soviet 7.one is of interest not only because of the increase in the labor pool, but also because of the social implications; behind the propagandistic demands and the administrative measures is a disregard of the social and cultural attitude which formerly prevailed in Germany, a 3isregard which is characteristic of the Sovietization of the Central German area, The Soviet Zoae Labor Lav of 19 April 1950 obligES "all plants and admini,- trations to fi]1 s]1 gobs as far as possible with wou:en workers." This is merely the formal statement of the goal set in the Five-Year plan. However, since the law excludes only expectant or nursing mothers from mine work or night work, it violates the established German principle of specific protection of women from physically unsuitable work. A special law of 27 September 1950, called, ironically, the Lax for the Protection of Mothers and Children and for Wcmen's Rights, decrees specifically in Pa:agre-~h 19: "The work of women is production shall not be limited to the traditional women's vocations, but shall extend to all branches of production." Sovietization of Agriculture (see Figure 1) One of the first Soviet measures after occupation was the e1Lsi.natiou of large land holdings. During the first year after the war, about one fifth of the total arable land was divided up end parceled out to new owners, and other former estate property, totaling about half that amount,, became public p; zrty. About:': 11,000 owners, mostly fanners, wer? deprived of their property without indemnity. However, the predominantly agricultural character of Central Germany did nut change; in fact it vas intensified by 210,000 new peaa- aiite, most]y refugees. r^urthenuore, t:~e lard holdings of 80,u00 2'ormer sma:11 farmers were increased. The utilization :,i the arable land in Central G-rmany has been more or lees constant for decade;, because of climatic and geological conditions, and it has not c'nanged appre_iably since the war. Areal increase in agricultural production can be achieved only by intensifyin? soil fertilization and by making available sufficient mechanical equip:cent. With the establishment of a system for assuring t:~~ rational use of the available agricultural machinery, the Soviets laid the foundation for an effective sovietization of Central Ger- man agriculture. The MfIS (machine rental stations) are not only foothcl~s for ideological peaetr:tion, but are also important instruments for regizcenting farm operations and making the farmers deperdert. Since the beginning oi' 1951, the local MAS and the shops and schools connected xith Them have been united under the designation "Federation of People-Owned MAS" and are on a par with other so-called people-owned enterprises. In J.946 and 1947, the number of cattle was about one third lower than the prewar number. By 1950, the number of cattle and pigs reportedly was about equsl to the prewar figure. The Five-Year Plan calls for the slaughtered weight of cattle to be increased by 19 percent between 1950 and 1955? Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060110-1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060110-1 Sovietization oP Industry and Hand Trades (See Tables 5, 6, and Fi?~ure _) The heavily industrialized Central German area provided the Soviets xith a rich source of booty, xhich they proceeded to exploit by means of Atsmantlinge and requisitions from current productic:r.. To be sure, this highly industrialized Central German area is short oY rax materials", but its textile production, con- centrated in the Sachsen-Thueringen area, is of high export value, althougu there is an inaut'ficiency of spinning mills. P~?om 1936 to 1939, the output of the capital goods industries increased 00 percent. It increased further during the xar is spite oY bombi7gs, and by 1944 amounted to almost 250 percent of 1936 production. In thr: same period, the production of rax materials and poxer increased by 50 perce. en this othet? hand, even in the xar years, the production of consuaers' goods declined con- siderably. Tho Soviets thus took over an indvstrial pntentiai with the most rx~?~.r.:1 equipment, especially for machine and vehicle constrrtion, aircraft cnnstrcc- tion, and chemicals. and electric poxer. ?liemanil.ing operations in there fie?;~s xere particularly rexarding fer the Soviets, and the consequent declu?:~ i.n pro- duction x?< mist keenly felt in these industries: in 1946, capital goods produc- tion amounted to ba}sly i0 percent of 1944 pro;i?::ction. In the rar material:: industries, p:.r~icul_iriy minim, it was morn alvsn- tageous for the Soviets to take over the industry itselT rather than to remove the production ma:hinery. In the fall of 1946, the so-called SAGs (Soviet Corporations) xeiE formed. By 1949, the SAGS controLed about 25 percent oY all Soviet Zone industrial production; in the consumers' goods industry, cont:?oi xas not very extensive, but in the chemical industry, the Soviets controlled over 50 percent, in metallurgy, 46 percent, in the electrical :nduetry, 41 per- cent, and in mining, 36 percent. Industrial pleats xhose production offered the Soviets no especially at- tractive proYits, but for xhich they could find an excuse for expropriation, were declared people-oxaed enterprises. Private industry, according to +.';e 1951 plan, ie to be reduced .:0 23.4 percent by the eno o: the year, largely as a result o^ chs-ineling new investments into the people-owned enterprises. Under the contract 6yst~m developed in 194y, priva+,e enterprises, doxn to the smallest ones, have become directly dependent upon those industries which have Flan quotas and xhich can allot vor:: to supplier plant: as they see fit. Ac- tually, only the people-owned enterprises and the SAGS have quotas, so pri- vate industry is at their mercy in the matter of or-~rs and, ccen more, in the matter of obtaining rax materials. Thus the Soviet.. :an regu?+,te the tempo of sovietization of the remaining private enterprises as they wi.ah. Rsnd trades were fi.ially inc~rpornted into the contract system by the order of 9 August 1950, which stAtes spec ificnlly: "The relationship be- tween hand trades and the rest of the econowy is to be regulated by contract.'' The Soviets are removing hand trades as a poss?.bl~ focal point fo:? tie es- tablishment of a nex group of entrepreneurs. This throttling of individual initiative has not been replaced in the sovietized enterprises by a stimula- tion of group initiative-among workers in the large plants, as in Western Ger- many. Paragraph 4 of the Soviet Zone Iabor I.aw of 19 April 1950 says: "In ' our nev democratic order, in which the key industries belong to th^ people, the right of xorkers to codetermination in manAgement is realize3 through the democratic state organs." Realization oi' the Five-Year Flan wiL depend largely on whether the completely nationalized power industry can keep pace with the planned indus- trial expansion. The plan cal]s for a 70-percent increase in the output of electric poxer. In 1950, the Soviets claimed that they hod reached the prewar Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060 STAT Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060110-1 level of industrial production. This is a propaganda claim based on comparison of noncooparable fif[ures. The German Institute for Bcoaomic Research has cal- culated, after ad~vating the claimed plan results of complete iVlfillment of the 1950 plan, that at beet n production level of 84 percent can have been at- tained. This figure ie far beiov the production lev.:l in West Germany. IIovever, the actual social and economic level of the Soviet Zone is not clear from such a camparieou. It is customary to regard as production only that pest of the output which is actually marketable. Nonmarketable re,jecta are merely counted in the coat of plant operation. In the war years and. before the currency reform, these re~ecta found their way to the market; in tae Soviet Zone's planning system the use of these rejects is the general rule, and e~-e:*~ euch-re~ects as are reclaimed or are r.fused by the acceptance co~missioss ~.. listed in the production statements. The system of comparative reporting, "Quota versus Actual Froductioa," forces the adoption of this procedure. But only part of the useful output of th= Soviet Zone industry 1s avail- able for domestic consumption. Reparations and direct and indirect siphoning off of industrial out?.++t. by the Soviets ,jeopardizes the supply of the Soviet Zone popu]ation. In 1y5O, it least on_ third of industrial producti?~n xas drain off by the Soviets in one xay or another. The loss to the cony mars through inferior quality of the products can be estimated at 12-13 percent of the total production. Ftiu-thermore, almost one tenth of the zone's output -?as required for the refugees xho entered the zone after the end of the var. Only the amount left after all these deductions can be considered as normal civilian supply, which may properly be compared with prewar supply. That means that the Soviet Zone's domestic supply of industrial goods oY a sorts, including capital goods, xas not even half 1:tsat of Weat Germany; if one dis- regards capital goods tha comparison is even more unfavorable. Sovietization of Trade (Sae Table 7) Since the Soviet planning system controls all marketing operstiors, the traditional wholesale trade is the zone Zuickly lost its nat.u-al fielZ of activity. The nationalization of xholesslr. trade through the establishment of so-called trade offices and trade centers has already b.en com~;ieted. With the founding oi' the HO (Trade Organization) in November ly4d, th^_ nati:,ntili- zation xas ertended to retail trade. Up to that time, crop:rative retail trace had been alloxed is a modest degree. For c or 3 years prior to :!i+establish- ment of the H0, consumer cooperatives had accounted f:,r about 17 ;~~:.^~:_ ~. n'_' retail trade transactions. Hoxever, the HO stures dr=.w a ::^nE?.derabi': p~. of the retail trade away, because they were privileged tc >li rntionc:~i fog.:- stuffs and consumers' goods in free track-, although at excre~sive prices. .r~- vate retailers have been degraded practically to distributors of rationed goods. At present, about one half the retail transactions go through pri- vate hands, but the complete sovietization o(' retail tre.fle ie obvicusly act far off. Social Conditions in Soviet Zone (See Tables 8, 9) The reduction of prlvate property by expropriations, the typing up of cash by blocking accounts, and the develuaticn through currency reform have destroyed the basic property structure in the Soviet Zone. Nex savings are completely negligible; it is practically imp:.~~r,ible to form private capital. There is a tight exchange barrier between Ens: and Wes+. Germany; flight of capital in the form of exchange of 1:-et marks for West csrrs is prevented, sad the cash funds of every Soviet Zone inhabitant are k~_p?. u^.ier strict control. The curve of variation of legally acquired irco;aes has flattened r~?.L considerably; on the other hand, there is a greater 3;ifcrenti=tion than be- fore in the range oi' uagee and salnries, since the incasti~_ :.,stem, of STAT Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060110-1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060110-1 netiviet wages and bonuses occasionally permits 'rorkers to reach an income level far above the average, a level which is still nominA~~V lower than in reductlorn ads s result of theeet ehsystemeoi'Ldaalipzice3levels.g Fevggoodsve can be bought at prices comtnenaurate with those in bleat Germany, and these are almost nlvays rationed goods. In an East-West comparison of the vur- chasing power of poorly paid *+orkers, the results would be about equal. But if one takes into account the poorer quality of the Soviet Zone "ationed goods and realizes that they must be supplemented by purchases from the H0, then the comparison is not favorable. According to the German Instituta for Economic Research, a worker in the Soviet Zone would have had to pay 260 East m,:ks to attain a standard equal to that of a West G-:rman xorker with an incoma of i50 bleat marks. A comparison based on a higher standard of living shows the p~o- ai'essive reduction in purchasing power mentioned above: a West Germ;~.c;tead-? and that coats 255 West mark; would requir~> sn Eat;t German income of 65~ hest marks. In other words, the purchasing power of an income o*' 200 East :.sr1:s in the Soviet Zone is only 66 percent of the purc.~:.sing power. of the same income in West marks is iles~ CexnianY; with an income of 350 East mark^ the ratio drops to only 50 percent; and with an ycoLe of 600 East marks, it dr~>?c? to 40 percent. ~ppended tables anc figures follow) Table 1. Nominal Yalue of Goods and Services Producai in West Germany and Scvi.t Zone (Estimated in bi.)lion Reichsmarics or Deutsche marks. Cheinaeov^r to Deutsche marks occured Sn mi4-lg4a.) -' ' ~ L ~C~ -i= ~ ~~ 104C Consumers' goods and services 30 40 5- 13 li, to Investments 2 5 3 1 Public requirements 5 ~ F 3 ~ 5 j 3 ,~ Deliieries to occupying powere ~ - 4.? !i ~ 4 5 4.3 Net product 43 i'i 'i3 20 ~~.5 X5,5 Minus deliveries t~ occupying powers 6 5 4.7 4.5 4.5 4.3 Plus foreign aid 1 _ _ - - Available far German use 38 53 70.3 15.5 18 21.2 * Price ad,7uatments arz necesa~ry to make the comparative figures mean- ingful. Amouate ranging from 4 to 4.5 billion R~ichsmsr;c:. or Deutsche narks a year must be deducted from the Soviet Zone fLgures because of the inflated prices resulting Prom liquor tax, free market sales, and HO (Srade Organization) sales; about 1.5 billion Reichsmarlw or DeiY scha marks a year must be added to the Soviet Zone figures to make up for the unrealistically lox prices of Soviet Zone reparations s:iipmente. STAT Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060110-1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060110-1 Table 2. Manpower Struotuie Before sad diter the liar (ia thoueande); Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060110-1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060110-1 ~' Discrepancies ir. totals are due to rourdin,~ off numbers to thousands. ~` ~i12 zatnf~~Iy employe3 and the unemployed; 1939 includes pereona'in obligstory military and labor sarvice. Uaemplaye~ in3ependent workers. 1_ Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2011/10/06 :CIA-RDP80-00809A000700060110-1 Fercentage Total Men Warren of Women (in thousands) 193? 17 *~ay+F 7,685 4,861 2,824 36.7 1845 Dec 5,^'.'! 3,138 z,SFy 45.2 lo4F, 29 Oct 7,7+t1 4,268 .~,73 44. , 19~ Dec 7,489 4,126 3,364 , 44. ~i 1947 Dec 7,822 4,478 3,344 , 5:2.7 1948 Dec 7,762 4,676 ly4y 3o Jun** 7,580 4,631 3,9~ ;>8.9 1949 SeP 7,706 4,727 2,079 38.7 1950 30 ,7uA 7,622 4,723 2,898 38.0 1939 17 Hay* Dependent Work 5,742 ers*~* 3,921 1,82'- 31. 1946 29 oct 5,476 ? 18': 2,292 41.? 1949 3o Jun 5,916 '.,7~?; 2,zo7 37.3 1950 3o sun 5,996 3,816 2,180 3b.4 1955 Plan 7,600 4,400 3,200 42 Sndependent Workers 1939 17 Mayes 954 799 155 15.2 1946 29 oct 1,224 919 305 24.9 1949 15 Apr 1,043 844 i99 19.1 1950 3o dun 1,028 837 192 18.6 Feaily ?ambers Assisting IndepFndent Workers :