LETTER TO C. DOUGLAS DILLON FROM JOHN A. MCCONE

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP80B01676R002900140016-1
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
K
Document Page Count: 
13
Document Creation Date: 
December 12, 2016
Document Release Date: 
March 11, 2002
Sequence Number: 
16
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
May 4, 1962
Content Type: 
LETTER
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP80B01676R002900140016-1.pdf788.46 KB
Body: 
Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80BO1676R002900140016-1 ER 62-292 3/a Hr. C. MUM Sesreta of the Treasury Washington.. D.C. c yu for sending s a or tb* apeeeh Leh y daIlvered to 2 April 199 to the Now Y wk Ec is Cit. an deLtgtted to ba its a 3 grill ned it ixztereet . (Signed JOHN Ill. ;icCONE John A. NbCom 3 y 62) Distribution: Orig - Add 1 - DCI via/read 1 - DDCI " ER W/basic 2 - S3Grogan v/speech Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80BO1676R002900140016-1 -- D ~ 1. CENTRAL INTELLIGENCE AGENCY OFFICIAL ROUTING SLIP DATE Col. Grogan For your information and for whatever action yOu may deem as appropriate. FOLD HERE TO RETURN TO SENDER FROM: NAME, ADDRESS AND PHONE NO. 5/4/62 FORM NO. 237 Use previous editions U.S. GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE: 1961 0-587282 2-61 11 I FC;IR Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80B01676R002900140016-1 SECRETARY OF THE TR AiRY May 2, 1962 Because of its bearing on the Trade and Tax bills, I think you may be interested in the speech I delivered last week to the New York Economic Club, a copy of which is attached. Douglas Dillon Executive Registry Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80B01676R002900140016-1 Approved For Rase 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80B01676ROS2900140016-1 TREASURY DEPARTMENT Washington FOR RELEASE 6:30 P.M., EST TUESDAY, APRIL 24, 1962 REMARKS OF THE HONORABLE DOUGLAS DILLON SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY BEFORE THE ECONOMIC CLUB OF NEW YORK TUESDAY, APRIL 24, 1962, 6:30 P.M.,EST "RESPONDING TO THE CHALLENGE OF THE COMMON MARKET" The fabulous success-of the European Common Market presents this Nation with a challenge -- an opportunity -- and a promise: -- A challenge, because the industrial might and know-how of the Common Market make it a formidable competitor in the trading centers of the world. -- An opportunity, because the increasing demands of its thriving peoples are creating potentially vast new markets for American products. -- A promise, because the prospering nations in the Common Market now have the capacity to assume a larger and more appropriate share of the cost of strengthening the defensive forces of freedom and of assisting less fortunate nations along the path to progress. In responding to the challenge of the Common Market, we must realize that we live today in a highly competitive, fast-changing new world, in which trade barriers are rapidly being lowered or eliminated. President Kennedy's new trade program recognizes that without mutual tariff reductions, we will be hobbled in our efforts to compete with foreign producers and will be unable to take advantage of the opportunities posed by the Common Market. But trade legislation alone will not keep up competitive. We must compete effectively. This calls for ingenuity and. energy in developing new products and new markets, and it demands that the costs of American production be competitive. These are not simple tasks. They will require concerted effort by every sector of our economy. For every sector of our D-470 Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80B01676R002900140016-1 Approved For Re,se 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80B01676RQ900140016-1 economy is intimately involved. There is far more at stake than trade. The real stakes are the continued strength and well-being of this Nation and the survival of freedom itself. In shaping our over-all response to the challenge of the Common Market, we must keep constantly in mind these major national economic goals: First, achieving the more rapid rate of economic growth that we must have to solve our persistent unemployment problem, as well as to remain competitive. Second, maintaining reasonable price stability, which is essential if we are to increase our export sales, solve the imbalance in our international payments, and ensure the full enjoyment of their later years by senior citizens living on fixed retirement incomes. Third, achieving and'maintaining balance of payments equilibrium in a fashion that will permit'us to carry our proper share of the free world's defense and furnish a fair proportion of the assistance needed by the newly-developing nations. Growth is essential to our continuing prosperity because we must grow faster if we are to provide reasonably full employment for our swelling labor force. And only through rapid growth can new technology be put to work fast enough to keep us competitive. Growth is also essential to long term equilibrium in our balance of payments. We cannot hope to solve our payments difficulties if our growth rate continues to drag along at little more than half that of our friends and competitors in Western Europe and Japan. If we are to increase our growth from the rate of about three per cent a year that characterized the Fifties, to the 4-1/2 per cent that has been set by the Organization For Economic Cooperation And Development as a fair and reasonable goal for its members in the Sixties, we must have an economic environment that will stimulate productive investment and business activity. Demand must be adequate to absorb our production. We must make every effort to avoid recessions and, if they occur, to mitigate their effect. We must have a tax system that will stimulate both individual initiative and private investment. And we must have capital readily available to finance the needs of the economy. The Administration is moving actively in all these areas. The President has submitted a three-point program to the Congress that would improve the effect of the so-called automatic stabilizers in Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80B01676R002900140016-1 Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80BO1676R0022900140016-1 -VO moderating recessions. These automatic stabilizers are the increased unemployment payments and the decline in income tax revenues, particularly in corporate taxes, that automatically accompany any recession. Their action simultaneously decreases the government's tax take from the economy, and increases government payments in the area where they will do the most good. These automatic stabilizers have softened post-war recessions, which have had little resemblance to the depressions of earlier days.. Even so, we still spend too much time in recession and it is these recessions, moderate though. they have been, that are primarily responsible for our inadequate growth rate over the past decade. The President's program is designed to give us the tools we need to effectively combat these economic slow-downs: First, there is a need for better unemployment insurance. This need became glaringly apparent during the past two recessions, when we were caught with an inadequate unemployment compensation system that made no provision for the long-time unemployed, whose ranks swell every time business slows down. Congress has twice been forced to improvise with temporary unemployment compensation measures. The time has clearly come to take account of those experiences and enact a permanent law along the lines proposed by the President, a law which would adequately meet the problem. Second, the President has asked for limited authority to order modest temporary tax reductions that would further speed the automatic reduction in tax revenues that has been so effective during recent recessions. While there is understandable reluctance to grant such new authority, the concept of temporary tax reduction as an anti-recession measure appears to be generally accepted. Limited authority to the President under strict Congressional control would seem the best way of carrying out this concept. The third element in the President's anti-recession program is limited standby authority to initiate or speed up public works programs of the type that could be gotten underway rapidly, and substantially completed within twelve months. These three new tools would greatly enhance our ability to deal with the economic slow-downs that have characterized our post-war economy. In so doing they should make possible a substantially more rapid rate of growth over the years ahead. Rapid growth in our free enterprise system also requires a tax setting conducive to risk-taking -- a setting that will give full play to individual initiative and effort -- one that will genuinely stimulate investment. Such a tax structure calls for a basic revision of our income tax system, and that is exactly what the Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80BO1676R002900140016-1 Approved For Reuse 2002/05/07: CIA-RDP80B01676R0900140016-1 - 4 - President has had in mind for the past year. At his direction, we in the Treasury have been working hard to develop such a new tax program. But taxes are complex. They effect every facet of our lives. They take time to develop, as well as to enact. The initial program submitted last year is still before the Congress. This has slowed our progress in developing the new program, but our work is progressing and we fully intend to submit proposals for overall reform of the income tax rate structure.- In the meantime, we are hopeful of rapid Congressional approval of the current tax bill, since its major element, the investment credit, is'absolutely essential both to our growth and to our competitive position in the world. During the past year, I have found general agreement that it is necessary to liberalize our treatment of depreciation so as to stimulate investment. A good deal can be done under present law, for our depreciation statutes are not as bad as they are often depicted. It is the administration of the law that has been primarily at fault. Revenue agents have been required to use as their guide for depreciation allowances, a bulletin put out by the Internal Revenue Service twenty years ago and never since modified. And, as if this obsolescence of the guidelines were not enough, it has also become clear that the basic concept in the guidelines of separate depreciable lives for each and every tool and machine brings with it a great deal of unnecessary paperwork and argument. We intend to thoroughly revise and update these instructions. In our revision we will set forth broad classes of equipment to replace the 5000 odd items presently listed in Bulletin F, as it is called. Treasury studies, underway for nearly two . years -- and which for the first time take account of anticipated future obsolescence -- indicate that we will also be able to substantially reduce the average guideline lives for depreciation. In the case of the textile industry, where the task has already been completed, the reductions averaged forty per cent. However, since our manufacturers are already legally writing off their equipment at considerably faster rates than are provided in existing guidelines, the actual benefit of the revisions now underway will be considerably less than the projected percentage reductions in the guidelines. Present rates of depreciation are the result of agreements with revenue agents. These agreements have not been reached easily. They have involved a great deal of debate and compromise. Sometimes, they have required resort to the courts. Such unfortunate controversy has been the inevitable result of out-of-date guidelines which forced revenue agents to rely upon their own judgment in determining depreciable lives for the various pieces of equipment used by industry. One of our major aims in modernizing administrative depreciation practices is to reduce this area of contention and uncertainty to a minimum. We are confident that very significant progress is possible. Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80B01676R002900140016-1 Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80BO1676R002900140016-1 5 - But all we can accomplish by the administrative route is not sufficient to meet the needs of American industry in today's competitive world. All of our competitors in Europe, Canada, and Japan go farther by providing some form of special incentive to modernize. Some of them use unrealistically short lives, which work in the same manner as the five-year amortization we have used in- times of defense emergency. Others provide substantial special write-offs in the first year, usually called initial allowances. More recently, some of them have been turning to allowances over and above one hundred per cent of depreciation -- the same principle we are advocating in our investment credit. Such investment allowances are presently in effect in Belgium, the United Kingdom', and the Netherlands, and are now being adopted in Australia. The resulting contrast with current practices here is dramatic. Taking the case of a piece of equipment, which has a fifteen-year life under our present laws, we find that manufacturers in Western Europe and Japan can write off an average of twenty-nine per cent on similar equipment in the first year, compared to only 13.3 per cent for American industrialists. Modernizing administrative practices can close only a small percentage of this gap. If American industry is to compete effectively, we must provide special incentives comparable to those available abroad. The only possible question can be over the way in which these incentives should be provided. The investment credit is one such way -- and an extremely effective one. The combination of an eight per cent investment credit and modernized administrative procedures will put American manufacturers on a comparable footing with their foreign competitors as.far as investment in machinery and equipment is concerned. The same result can, of course, be accomplished by various methods of accelerating depreciation beyond what is called for by realistic depreciable lives. But in the Treasury's view, the investment credit has two clearcut and important advantages over all methods of accelerated depreciation. The first is that the investment allowance or credit, utilizing the principal of an allowance over and above 100 per cent of original cost, increases the profitability of a given investment far more than any equivalent acceleration of depreciation. One of-the most thorough studies on the subject, prepared for its membership in the machine tool industry by the Machinery and Allied Products Institute, finds that on a typical fifteen year asset, an eight per cent investment credit has the same effect on profitability as a forty per cent first year depreciation write-off. Let me repeat that. The eight per cent investment credit which we are recommending has the same effect on profitability of investment as a special forty per cent first-year depreciation write-off. However, when we calculate the effect of these two methods on our tax revenues, we find that the first-year revenue cost of the credit is $1.35 billion, while the cost of the forty per cent initial allowance is $5.3 billion. Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80BO1676R002900140016-1 Approved For Re else 2002/05/07: CIA-RDP80B01676R0900140016-1 6 - Over a five-year period, assuming steady growth in the economy, the credit might cost something like $10 billion, compared to $24 billion for the comparable forty per cent first year write-off. Similar results are reached when we compare the cost of other methods of accelerating depreciation to that of the credit. I think you will all agree that government in these days should make every effort to get the most out of its dollars. Avoidance of waste is just as important in tax policy as it is in expenditure policy. And that is one very good reason why we prefer the investment credit to the more expensive and less effective route of accelerated depreciation. The second unique advantage of the credit is that it will not adversely effect costs or prices. Accelerated depreciation is often entered as an item of cost. This naturally inflates costs and shrinks profits, thus tending to promote the very price increases we must avoid. I think you are all aware that the single largest increase in general manufacturing costs over the past few years has come from the increased depreciation write-offs permitted by the 1954 law which updated and liberalized depreciation procedures. This increase in costs was fully warranted, since it recognized the actual obsolescence rates of machinery. That is what depreciation is for and this will, of course, also be the effect of our administrative reforms. However, when it comes to an incentive, over and beyond realistic depreciation, the situation is quite different. As I have pointed out, the use of accelerated depreciation for this purpose would be wasteful of the government's tax dollar as compared to the credit, and would also tend to distort earnings and prices. For these two reasons, we stand firmly for the investment credit approach as the most feasible and practicable method of providing the stimulus to investment in machinery and equipment that we must have if we are to achieve the rate of growth required for a competitive and reasonably fully-employed economy. Enactment of the investment credit also has an immediate importance. The greatest uncertainty and the major soft spot in our current economic situation is the indication that business investment over the next year may be inadequate to sustain the pace of our recovery. Enactment of the credit will immediately generate new business in the machine tool and allied industries and will accelerate the incorporation of the latest technology into our productive system. It will shorten the lag-time between development and manufacture of new products, and thus help to open up new markets. It will stimulate industrial expansion and thus help to create the new jobs we so badly need. In short it will give a lift to our economy in exactly the place where it is most needed and at the very time it is most needed. Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80B01676R002900140016-1 Approved For Ruse 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80B01676W900140016-1 - 7 - To the extent that investment is stimulated, new capital will be required. The national monetary and debt management policies that have been followed for the past year give assurance that the needed funds will be available at reasonable rates of interest. Today, with the recovery fourteen months old, the cost of new long-time corporate borrowing is lower than at any time since the economic advance got underway. At the same time, for balance of payments reasons, we have maintained and even moderately increased short-.term interest rates, so as to equalize them with those obtainable abroad. The investment credit, by promoting the use of modern, cost- cutting machinery, will help us to achieve our two other major economic goals: reasonable price stability and balance of payments equilibrium. Price stability is a must if we are to compete successfully in world market places, and it also makes for healthy economic and social conditions at home. Fortunately, conditions today in the United States are favorable to price stability -- if only we use restraint. The strongest type of inflation is classical demand-inflation -- too much money chasing too few goods. It is because of the danger of demand-inflation that we are wary of budget deficits. For Federal budget deficits create purchasing power. Whenever capacity is tight and demand is strong, deficits lead almost inevitably to a rise in prices which diminishes the value of all savings and helps no one but the lucky speculator. However, for at least the past four or five years, we have had no problem with demand-inflation. We have not known reasonably full employment since 1957. The slack'in our economy was revealed by the fact that the record $12-1/2 billion deficit of fiscal year 1959 had no noticeable effect on wholesale prices. Neither has there been any effect from the $7 billion deficit we are running this fiscal year. As a matter of fact, wholesale prices are lower today than a year ago. I by no means wish to imply that we should not be concerned by deficits. But I do want to point out that the effect of a deficit on a slack economy is totally different from the effect of the same deficit on a full employment economy. We cannot afford deficits at full employment. Indeed, we anticipate substantial surpluses in such periods. With the prospect of rapid economic growth that led to last January's forecast of a gross national product of $570 billion for 1962, the President wisely presented a balanced budget. While the January and February slow-up has made the achievement of this goal considerably more difficult, it is still possible. If we achieve it, there is no reason why we should not have a balanced budget as well. The main point to remember about our deficits is that they have been a reflection of the uneven pace of our economy. Cure the recessions and the deficits will also disappear. Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80BO1676R002900140016-1 Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80BO1676R 2900140016-1 While we are on the subject of fiscal policy, I would like to digress for a moment to compare our experience with that of some of our European friends. There is a common misconception, both here and abroad, that our fiscal or budgetary performance is poor compared to such countries as France, the United Kingdom, and West Germany. That is simply not so. A recently completed study which converts the budgets of those countries to our accounting system, shows that our record is quite good. By adapting their data to our budget accounting methods Germany would show a.bud get deficit in every one of the past four years -- the only years in which her post-war defense expenditures have been of any significance. France would show them in every one of the past ten years. And the United Kingdom would show deficits in nine of the past eleven years -- and, in this connection, the Chancellor of the Exchequer has just forecast another deficit for the upcoming fiscal year. In contrast, the consolidated cash budget of the United States has been in deficit in only six out of the last eleven years. Perhaps even more impressive is the fact that, over those same periods of time, the cumulative American deficit, as a percentage of gross national product, was the lowest. France's was the highest, with Germany next, and the United Kingdom third. It is worthy of note that France and Germany, which run persistent deficits in their budgets, also run the greatest and most persistent surpluses in their balance of payments. That, of course, is not because of their deficits, but rather because they have maintained competitive prices on their export goods -- the key to payments surpluses -- and have maintained them in the face of continuing full employment. Despite the fortunate absence of demand-inflation from the American scene, we must continue to guard vigilantly against wage-price inflation, which can be just as dangerous and can strike at any time. If we are to avoid this type of inflation, prices should remain level or drop, and wage increases should be governed by increases in labor productivity. To help in defining these limits, the President's Council of Economic Advisors, in their annual report, set forth guidelines based on the performance of our economy, which has shown an average annual increase in productivity of from 2-1/2 to 3-1/2 per cent. As long as our economy continues to grow and productivity continues to increase at this rate, it should be possible to absorb wage increases of like magnitude with- out any increases in price. And remember that productivity also applies to capital. As the productivity of capital increases, there should also be room for increases in profits, to correspond with the increased wages of labor. All this will be possible if management and labor work jointly to make it possible -- bearing the national interest in mind at all times Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80BO1676R002900140016-1 Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80BO1676R00_ 22900140016-1 - 9 - Price stability is essential if we are to achieve our third major goal -- balance of payments equilibrium. Without it, there can be no hope of achieving balance unless we invoke drastic actions that would do as much harm as good. That was the major reason for the President' ' s great concern when, for a few days earlier this month, price stability anneared to be threatened. Growth and price stability must both make their contribution to improving our payments problem by. keeping our exports competitive. But still more.,js needed. For we have been forced to assume exception .l _ 'responsibilities in the defense of the free world. Those responsibilities put a great drain on our balance of payments -- a drain which has recently averaged about $3 billion a year. We must work. to reduce this outflow by cutting out all non-essential costs and by obtaining offsetting payments from our European Allies for U. S. military materiel and services. A good start has been made. You have heard the President state that Secretary McNamara has accepted a goal of a billion-dollar reduction in the net outflow of defense dollars. About half of that goal has already been achieved through the recent agreement with West Germany, by which she is sharply increasing her purchases of U. S. military equipment. We are hopeful that similar arrangements can be made with other countries. The rest of the billion-dollar goal will have to be achieved through economies in dollar expenditures. We are also using every opportunity to channel the maximum amount of our foreign aid funds into purchases in the United States, where they do not affect our balance of payments. But there is another important area affecting our balance of payments where action is required if we are to achieve overall balance. I refer to the steadily increasing outflow of private investment capital. The easiest way to handle this problem would be to utilize the standard European method -- exchange controls. But we are firmly opposed to this approach, and so are pursuing two other avenues: We are working with our European friends in the OECD to liberalize their controls on capital movements, and we are urging them to develop their own internal capital markets so that they will not have to rely so heavily on our capital market. This is a slow process, but progress is being made. Our second method of slowing the capital outflow is by eliminating that portion of the outflow, perhaps as much as ten per cent, that is induced by tax reasons. That is the basic aim of the Administration's foreign tax proposals. Those proposals are not directed against foreign investment as such. They merely attempt to put investment in the Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80BO1676R002900140016-1 Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80BO1676RO 900140016-1 Aw, other industrialized countries on a par with investment here at home, as far as tax treatment is concerned. Their enactment would not only reduce the outflow of capital for direct investment in the other industrialized countries by some ten per cent, it would also remove the artificial tax incentive to retain profits abroad and so would improve their return flow to the United States by rougly the same amount. The resulting overall balance of payments improvement should be something like $400 million a year. The great bulk of foreign investment -- and I am confident it'is not made for tax purposes -- would continue as in the past. But that relatively small part that is purely tax-induced -- and we all know that it does exist -- would be eliminated, with substantial benefit to our balance of payments. At the outset of my remarks, I said that the Common Market presents us with a challenge. But the greatest challenge lies within ourselves. We have the means at hand to solve our economic problems -- if only we will use them wisely and well. The most important is the stimulation of additional private investment in productive equipment. We must use that means to the full, and in a manner that will not jeopardize the national interest by short- sighted decisions -- be they public or private. If we do so, we can make significant progress toward achieving our goals of more rapid growth, price stability, fuller employment, and payments equilibrium. We can move boldly to take advantage of the competitive challenge of the Common Market, secure in the knowledge that our Nation is capable of seizing opportunities in foreign trade to help make a reality of America's vast promise of a fuller life for our own people and for free peoples everywhere. Approved For Release 2002/05/07 : CIA-RDP80BO1676R002900140016-1