YOUR 26 JUNE MEETING WITH AMBASSADOR MIDDENDORF

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
T
Document Page Count: 
26
Document Creation Date: 
December 22, 2016
Document Release Date: 
February 24, 2010
Sequence Number: 
7
Case Number: 
Publication Date: 
June 25, 1985
Content Type: 
MEMO
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8.pdf1.73 MB
Body: 
Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 TOP SECRETI The Director of Central Intelligence \\ a.hingion. D.C. NiO State Dept. review completed National Intelligence Council MEMORANDUM FOR: Director of Central Intelligence Deputy Director of Central Intelligence NIC 03255-85 25 June 1985 FROM: David B. Low National Intelligence Officer for Economics SUBJECT: Your 26 June Meeting with Ambassador Middendorf 1. As you know, Ambassador Middendorf is moving from his post as Permanent Representative to the OAS to become US Ambassador to the EC. 2. Topics of discussion are likely to be as follows: A. US-EC Trade Relations. US-EC trade relations have been the subject of review in the Administration over recent months. Attachment A is a summary of US strategy on this topic recently prepared for the Economic Policy Council. The President decided last week to take action under Section 301 of the Trade Act against discriminatory tariff treatment by the EC on imports of US citrus products. We can anticipate an adverse EC reaction and some form of retaliation by the EC. See Attachment B for talking points on the above-mentioned strategy paper, including the citrus case. B. US Agricultural Export Enhancement Program. US agricultural exports have declined substantially from the 1981 record level of 164 million tons valued at $44 billion. Current Administration estimates indicate that 1985 exports may fall Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 SUBJECT: DCI 26 June Meeting with Ambassador Middendorf to a value of $30 billion, representing a significant loss of overseas markets. In a compromise with key farm state Senators, the Administration has committed up to $2 billion in the asset value of CCC-owned commodities over the next three years for an "export enhancement" program targeted at specific markets and specific commodities. The objective is to increase US farm exports and to encourage trading partners to begin serious negotiations on agri- cultural trade problems. An example of how the program would work is at Attachment C. The program is in large part targeted at the EC and the French in particular. This program has already prompted critical but cautious responses from other agricultural exporters 3. You will recall, of course, that the Ambassador has sent you copies of many speeches which he has made on the topic of promoting private sector development in Latin America. A copy of his most recent letter and statement are attached at Attachment E. In addition, you will recall that you have written to Pat Buchanan endorsing the Ambassador's proposal of White House backing for a conference at Georgetown University on international private enterprise. Attachments: A. Strategy Paper on US-EC Trade Relations B. Talking Points on the Strategy Paper C. Export Enhancement Program Example E. Letter and Attachment from Ambassador Middendorf 25X1 25X1 25X1 25X1 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Copy 1 - DCI 2 - DDCI 3 - Spec Assist 4 - Executive Secretary Executive Registry (w/o Att. D) 5 - DD/OGI 6 - NIO/Econ (David Low) 7 - A/NIO/Econ NIO/Econ Chrono File (w/o Att. D) 8 - NIO/Econ File 9-10 NIO/Econ Copies Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 UNDER SECRETARY OF STATE FOO ECONOMIC AFFAIRS June 11, 1985 CONFIDENTIAL MEMORANDUM FOR MR. ROGER PORTER THE WHITE HOUSE SUBJECT: Strategy Paper on US-EC Trade Relations In response to the request of the Economic Policy Council at its meeting of June 5, I enclose a paper prepared jointly by the Department of State and the Office of the US Trade Representative on a strategy for US-EC trade relations. The paper has been approved by Deputy Secretary Dam and Ambassador Smith. I assume you will circulate it to the members of the Council in advance of the meeting on June 14. CONFIDENTIAL DECL: OADR Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 CONFIDENTIAL STRATEGY FOR US-EC TRADE RELATIONS I. Introduction In a sense, US-EC trade relations have been "poor relatives" of our security ties through NATO and bilateral relations with member states. In turning over trade issues to the Commission, our European allies have tended to see them as on a separate and unrelated track. This dichotomy, inherent in the formation of the EC, becomes a particular problem only if trade issues are handled by the Commission with little or no sensitivity to their impact on the international trading and monetary system. This now seems to be the case. At the working level a degree of mutually reinforcing frustration has entered into the treatment of issues on both sides of the Atlantic. Sho such trends continue, the resulting threat to Eti-iiiI ~lnteZ nal undermine the political/security Alliance, which rests on an assumption of economic_ as rreli as st_ra*pgac cooperation. The overriding objective of the proposals made in this study is to reinforce and deepen comprehension in Europe that economic issues are inseparable from the rest. To do this, we propose a strategy or ina ing US approac es to individual issues, with an eye to timing as well as to substance and to the effect actions in each individual area may have on other economic objectives, on the overall US-European relationship, and on Congressional support for maintaining the international trading system. In the end, despite our best efforts, it may not be possible to negotiate settlements of all our problems with the EC on terms consistent with our trade interests. Should this happen, we ought to work with the Community to limit the impact on other Ara 0f our relationship of any trade actions we take. Finally, in the event the EC is not able to muster Community-wide support for trade liberalization initiatives, we should not allow this policy divergence to weaken our own commitment to freer international trade. II. Inventory of Problems 1. Agriculture The EC is our second largest agricultural customer and our major competitor in world markets. Its Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) has encouraged over-production, and reduced our CONFIDENTIAL DECL: OADR Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 CONFIDENTIAL market access, a process we expect to continue as the Community moves to replace imported with domestically produced feed. CAP subsidies have played a large part in displacing US agricultural sales (as well as sales by other traditional exporters) in third country markets. The EC has adamantly resisted solutions it interprets as opening to question e CAP structure o ice supports, variable import levies and export subsidies. The US by contrast has signaled a willingness to place US agriculture on a more market-oriented footing. Citrus is only the most current example of our inability to resolve agricultural disputes with the under the GATT. Other flare-ups are likely in coming months over export subsidies. The EC Commission had received ayt rarity to negotiate a package deal on steel that resolves, at least temporarily, a contentious dispute over pipe for the All American Pipeline (AAPL). Secretary Baldrige will permit 100,000 tons of EC pipe to enter now, but he reserves the right to count the pipe against Pipe and Tube Arrangement limits later on, if the EC does not complete-negotiations for a comprehensive new steel reement ber The EC is also committed to reaching agreement on consultation products by July 15, 1985. Without this agreement, our many other restraint agreements could unravel. 3. New Round Strong French opposition and the "least common denominator" approach have resulted in an EC position which obstructs real progress while offering tepid public support. Differences over a comprehensive review of the international monetary system and CAP reform, and French doubts about its ability to compete in services, high tech and agricultural trade under new rules are behind their resistance to a new round. It is difficult to conceive of negotiations on agriculture resulting in real progress without EC participation. This is also true for changes in existing GATT rules, e.g. safeguards. Agreements on high tech or services are possible without EC participation, but their practical value will be limited. Many 'Cs will have jar less incentive to ioin a new round without a reduction in EC barriers to their trade and support for a stronger safeguard regime. CONFIDENTIAL Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 CONFIDENTIAL " 3 - 4. Enlargement Issues and GATT We want to work with the EC to assure that contemplated changes in the EC CXT (Common External Tariff) and the Spanish and Portuguese tariffs are acceptable and in accordance with GATT rules. We prefer that the industrial tariffs of the new entrants be set at the present CXT level since almost all Spanish and Portuguese tariffs are greater than the CXT. If there is a linear balancing of agricultural tariffs, there are extremely complex problems of bound and unbound tariffs that could affect billions of dollars of US agricultural exports to the EC-12. The Greek case demonstrated a fundamental disagreement over the application of GATT provisions on enlargement. The EC will be positioning itself to limit US exports, and we will refuse to pay twice, for trade lost through diversion to EC suppliers plus that lost because of higher tariffs. 5. Tech Transfer Policy ter export contr o.s is begin sj .g_-=_'____ ~~vprco offectc on cur relat: ? ~""' --s with our allies. They complain that our measures are aimed at maintaining high technology leadership and commercial advantage. Among measures cited by our allies are: curtailment of the dissemination of scientific and technical information and closing to foreign nationals of certain SST conferences; tighter distribution license regulations affecting re-export; increased DOD authority to review West-West export license applications; and new safeguard requirements on exports of supercomputers. We have stressed to our allies that our policies are not directed at restricting the legitimate flow of information to friendly free-world countries. We have offered to discuss specific instances in which they believe our policies or procedures are in fact constraining legitimate West-West technology flows. We also plan to use appropriate existing fora -- e.g. COCOM, OECD -- to reassure our allies regarding the intent of our policies. III. Relations With The Commission Our normal interlocutor on trade issues is the Commission, to which authority for trade negotiations -- bilateral and multilateral -- has been delegated by member states. Given the volume of two-way trade (over $100 billion) and direct investment (over $160 billion) involved, differences are not CONFIDENTIAL Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 CONFIDENTIAL surprising. Few of these issues are solved in formal negotiations at the technical level, where they tend to be treated as a zero-sum game. Successful resolution has generally been through ties we have established at the political level, either through our Ambassador to the EC, who is the cornerstone of the relationship, or directly by Washington officials (Cabinet/Sub-Cabinet to Commission; Assistant Secretaries to Directors-General). At these levels, we have in the past been fortunate to find senior Commission officials (i.e. Soames, Haferkamp, Davignon) who have been imaginative and strong enough to develop solutions which they were willing and able subsequently to sell to member states. Thus far, there are prnhl epee in Chin respect with t?he nrJ Snmmission. Some may simply be due to the fact that it is new and still settling in, and is concentrating first on internal issues -- enlargement, breaking down internal barriers, meeting the challenges of unemployment and high technology. Further, especially in External Affairs, the Commission may be relying too heavily on staff that has become inflexible in its approach to our bilateral problems. But, personalities may present longer-lasting difficulties. While Delors' first visit here served well in establishing personal coact with the President and key Cabinet members, he seems little inclined to get directly inM lved in trade issues_beyon t :he ex or a ion level, and his attitudes towards the United States seems at best ambiguous. Willy de Clercq, Commissioner for External Relations, has thus far been rigid and unwilling to take initiatives to resolve problems, although his May 31/ June 1 negotiations with Secretary Baldrige on pipe and tube m. represent a positive development. Perhaps reflecting in part his holdover status, Agriculture Commissioner Andriessen has until now been the key exception; he has shown some flexibility and courage in his discussions thus far. He has already met with Secretary Block, and will see Secretary Shultz and others later this month. IV. Relations with Member States Clearly, we must also tackle our problems from the member states side as well. Heads of state/government are clearly able, and indeed anxious to stake out national positions at the economic summits. In general, they place greater weight on bilateral ties, a plane on-which they can best exercise their personal authority and pursue their national and political interests. European Ministers, on the other hand, generally take greater comfort in the collective decision-making of the Community -- whether (as has been the case of France) to provide a useful shield for national objectives, or (for CONFIDENTIAL Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 CONFIDENTIAL 5 - smaller countries) to gain a stronger voice through cohesion. It is in our interest to increase consciousness in capitals that we consider US-EC differences a part of our bilateral relationships -- the blame for clashes cannot be shifted to an anonymous twelve-side Council of Ministers. By the same token, we need to understand better the domestic political imperatives behind each country's stance on a US-EC issue, bearing in mind that "coalitions" among member states vary with the subject matter. Working with the French, for example, may be more necessary, albeit more difficult, than "conspiring" with more like-minded member states such as the UK and FRG. We should not 1k^rr v?- 1.? s--- - _ , ---= - - . - or ui n itv This would be both contrary to US li ' po cy of forty years duration -- just reaffirmed by the President at Strasbourg -- and counterproductive to our immediate goals. There is a line, which varies with each issue, beyond which the member states, however their views may differ, will react to pressures by closing ranks behind a Community position, defending not only a policy but an institution they have all made political sacrifices to create, and whose continuation and vitality is central to their foreign policies. We will have to judge where this line is on each issue, and use whatever approach is suitable to try to avoid breaching that line. V. Strategy We have identified the following major objectives in US-EC trade relations during the months ahead (listed more or less in priority order): 1. Develop effective mechanism and tactics for successfully resolving bilateral trade disputes, including our expected differences in the GATT examination of EC enlargement. 2. Develop closer coordination on preparation for a new trade round. 3. Bring steel negotiations to successful conclusion. 4. Re-engage informal discussions about agriculture to work toward agreement to eliminate agricultural export subsidies. 5. Develop Quad consensus on rollback of protectionism along lines of our proposal last March. 6. Develop coordinated approach to MFA negotiations. CONFIDENTIAL Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 CONFIDENTIAL r ?- 6 - 7. Work to defuse concerns about restrictions on access to technology. Regarding the substance of our objectives, the following observations would guide our approach: Agriculture Through a combination of bilateral discussions with the EC, multilateral talks in the GATT, and, where necessary, trade actions to defend our interests, we need to persuade the Community that we have a common interest because of over- productiop-and--.' d et costs in bringing policy more in line with market forces and in imposing restraint on the use of agricultural export suhs;d. Furthermore, we need to make clear that market sharing, the Community's preferred approach to resolving our disputes in international markets, it not an acceptable substitute for discipline over export subsidies. At root, our task in arriving at a satisfactory arrangement governing steel trade is to convince the EC that its structural adjustment p ohlems rAnnof no exported to the United States. It will be extremely difficult for the Community to work out the internal burden sharing which is a prerequisite of any viable agreement with us. Our approach must be to use a judicious combination of carrots and sticks which leave no doubt in the Commission or the Member States that, either through an arrangement or through unfair trade cases, we will assure an.ecuuitable sharing of burdens as steel industries on both sides of the Atlantic pass through this painful period of adjustment. Our objective should be to reach an agreement this summer which permits us to .putthis issue behind s and concentrate our energies on addressing trade issues of the future. New Round We are convinced that greater liberalization of the world trade system is in the interest of all trading nations. Concerned that protectionist pressures in many countries, including the US as well as the EC and Japan, are leading toward trade restrictions, we believe a New Trade Round is necessary to regain momentum,Ln support of freer trade. Clearly, multilatera trade negotiations w 11 be more fruitful if they include all major trading partners. Our primary objective is full EC participation in the new round. However, CONFIDENTIAL Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 CONFIDENTIAL 7 if the Community fails to achieve a consensus on starting a new round or tries to impose conditions unacceptable to the US, we should move ahead in those areas, e.g. services or high technology product, in w c articipation although desirable, is not indispensable to some a i ional liberaliza- tion beyond current eve s n many of our other world markets. Initiation of negotiations with like-minded countries may -convince the Community not to stay or +be a;Aal;.,es If it does not, we can in any event begin to reduce some trade barriers among those countries willing to negotiate, as has been done, for example in the case of the MTN codes. EC Enlargement During the coming months negotiations will begin in the GATT to determine whether the Community of 12 meets GATT requirements for a customs union, and to work out bilateral claims arising from the tariff changes that accompany the enlargement. We must continue to make clear to the EC that, while we support enlargement, we will not avree to s tT~.~e barriers n rrort. Since a EC intends to reveal its proposed new tariff schedule in January 1986, we should use the intervening months to dissuade it from building the idea of such a "credit" into the new tariffs. There are several opportunities for advancing many of our objectives in coming months. However, there are also new initiatives which we should consider for enhancing the chances for success. A timetable for action includes the following events and opportunities: June through July -- Negotiations on steel, following up on Secretary Baldrige's agreement with de Clercq of June 1. -- Meeting of US-EC working group on high technology. -- Visit of Commissioner Andriessen, during which we can explore the possibilities for giving new impetus to our informal dialogue on agricultural issues at the Director General/Under Secretary level, as well as the future of the GATT Co-ittee on Trade in Agriculture. -- Quadrilateral (US, Japan, Canada, EC) meeting in Canada: an opportunity to discuss issues related to preparation of a new trade round; explore possibilities for advancing toward agreement on our rollback proposal, CONFIDENTIAL Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 CONFIDENTIAL 8 - and, if appropriate, to have an initial exchange on MFA negotiations. July or September -- Meeting of Senior Officials in GATT to begin preparations for new trade round. -- Meeting of Senior Agriculture officials in context of GATT Committee on Trade in Agriculture. November -- In addition to GATT Council meetings leading up to it, the annual meeting of GATT Contracting Parties in November will offer opportunities to discuss many of the issues involving our main objectives. December -- Meeting at Cabinet level between US and EC Commission. The key to a successful strategy lies in establishing the basis for a constructive relationship in the weeks ahead. Assuming a Presidential decision to retaliate on citrus, we ... ,ems ion ra s, with the nnun er-retaliation by the Ec wr? will be taking up their new jobs. This gives us an opportunity to begin building a new relationship. Particularly critical is the need to convince the Member States of the necessity of seeing that the positions they take in the EC Council affecting relations with the US are an important aspect of our bilateral relationship as well. The proposals outlined below are designed to lay special emphasis on engaging the Member States more forcefully in responsibility for US-EC relations. USTR-designate Yeutter plans post-Labor Day travel to Brussels and key EC capitals to review trade relations. His visit, which should be coordinated with the efforts of AmbassadorMMiidd ndc,rf, who-will take up his position at USEC in July, could convey at a high leve our concern ,. ~ '~ ji - and the implications as we see them, and possible ways of dealin Wore constructively with our mutual problem. He could CONFIDENTIAL Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 ,CONFIDENTIAL carry, or be preceded by, letter from the President _e If deemed useful, '151 ___. Assistant Secretary-level team could precede or follow this tour. The objective would be to bring back for EPC consideration recommendations about how best to construct and manage our trade relationship with the EC and to present options for dealing with each of the main issues on our agenda. Recommen- 4ations should include an assessment of which issues seem mos 1 y" to - 55- a negotiable over the near term and which may require some ac ion by the US, either to pave the way to a settlement or in lieu ne. We should make it clear that the purpose is not to negotiate about specific issues, but rather to take a close look at the relationship as such. There are a variety of new proposals for better management or internal strategy development and coordination which we could examine in the light of the tour. These include: (1) Creation of an informal Assistant Secretary/ Director General-level group which could meet once or twice a year to discuss underlying themes in the US-EC relationship. (If the first such meeting takes place in late October, it would serve both to follow up the Yeutter tour and help prepare for the December Cabinet-level meeting.) (2) Suggest a meeting between the Secretary of State and the Foreign Ministers of the EC "Troika" (the immediate past, present and future presidency countries), perhaps at the annual UNGA session in September. (3) Ensure that the opportunity of the December Cabinet level meetings with the Commission becomes the occasion f roman intensive review in the Cabinet of US-EC relations and he cooraination of *rateg;, for '?pal' Q with them- Provide for a similar internal review each Spring. The US Ambassador to the EC should participate directly in both meetings and their preparation. VI. Congress We need to make sure we're getting credit in Congress wherever possible for trade polio- For example, when the AMU dinnutp settlemen roc ess an _of the logiam of agricultural cases wit the Community. CONFIDENTIAL Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 CONFIDENTIAL 0 _ - Similar briefings should be arranged on the steel agreement and our negotiating objectives for renewal of the 1982 accord. Finally, we should discuss with key members our plans fnr .i:e of the ex and the potential need to modify it if a breakthrough on export subsidy talks occurs. If it's decided to send a team to Europe, Congress should be briefed to make sure this isn't seen as an effort to talk the problems to death. CONFIDENTIAL Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Iq Next 2 Page(s) In Document Denied Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 The Director of Central Intelligence Washington, D. C. 20505 j JbA 1985 The Honorable J. William Middendorf, II U.S. Ambassador to the organization of American States Room 6494, Department of State Washington, D. C. 20520 Thank you for your letter of May 28, 1985 and the enclosed address entitled 'Free Enterprise: Key to Latin American Economic Revival." As you well know, I concur with your views about the need for positive steps to expand private sector development in Latin America. While the measures you have mentioned are steps in the right direction, I believe that more imaginative mechanisms of US support will be required before we can expect any significant change. Sincerely, 7s/ Big William J. Casey Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 United States Department of State United States Permanent Mission to the Washington, D. C. 2052F'-"+' May 28, 1985 ~ r 2420 In spite of news reports to the contrary, the economic picture in Latin America has not substantially improved, even though 58 percent of the entire $11.5 billion increase in exports that the Latins registered last year worldwide came to the U.S., and despite the fact that they had a $20.7 billion trade surplus with us last year. For the near and long term, everybody has good reason to be worried about the debt and security problems in our hemisphere, and I fear that these problems are not going to improve until a basic restructuring of their economies takes place, redirecting them towards free enterprise. In our country, we take free markets and the free enterprise system for granted. What is overlooked is that most of the largest debtor countries in our hemisphere have over 50 percent of their productive economic activity owned by the government, with all of its potential for inefficiency and bureaucratic interference, to say nothing of official corruption. Inflation rates are skyrocketing. No substantial debt principal payments are being made, and interest payments are being financed largely through new loans. If the U.S. business cycle turns down, all hell could break loose and we must be aware of it. In 1981, Ronald Reagan began the deregulation of our economy and the creation of incentives for vigorous economic growth. Then Margaret Thatcher led the way in England with privatiza- tion, and now a number of Europeans are looking at these success stories as a model. Recently, several Latin countries have been revising their own views on the role governments should play in the market place. Working through the OAS, I have now visited every country in our hemisphere carrying President Reagan's free enterprise message. In this regard, you might be interested in the enclosed study--Free Enterprise: The Key to Economic Revival in Latin America--outlining solutions for freeing up these economies. The Honorable William J. Casey, Director of Central Intelligence Agency. Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Unless real progress is made in this direction, I fear the security troubles that are now largely confined to Central America (see my paper, Nicaragua: The Stolen Revolution, which I sent you last week) will proliferate from the Straits of Magellan to the Rio Grande. We need your help. With your own valuable contacts in the hemisphere, can you help us in this effort to spread the Reagan message? J. William Middendorf, II Ambassador Permanent Representative Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87MOO539ROO0901220007-8 Current Policy No. 692 Following is an address by Ambassador J. William Middendorf I1, U.S. Perma- nent Representatiru to the Organization of American States (OAS). beli)re the In- ternational Conference on Latin America sponsored by the Cen i.er f irr I n- ternation.al Relations, San Jose, Costa Rica, February 22, 1985. It is a pleasure for me to join the il- lustrious group here in the discussion of the conference theme: "Basic Freedoms in Latin America: Their Past, Present and Future Prospects." The fact that this historic conference is treating both the political and economic aspects of Latin America's situation is indicative of what Secretary of State George P. Shultz stated in his testimony before the Senate Committee on Foreign Relations, entitled The Future of America Foreign Policy: New Realities and New Ways of Thinking" [Current Policy No. 6501, January 31, 1985: The United States seeks peace and security; we seek economic progress; we seek to promote freedom, democracy, and human rights. The conventional way of thinking is to treat these as discrete categories of activity. In fact, as we have seen, it is now more and more widely recognized that there is a truly profound connection among them. And this has important implications for the future. Secretary Shultz expanded on these points by saying: ... it is more and more understood that economic progress is related to a political en- vironment of openness and freedom. It used to be thought in some quarters that socialism was the appropriate model for developing J. William Middendorf 11 Free Enterprise: Key to Latin American Economic Revival United States Department of State Bureau of Public Affairs Washington, D.C. countries because central planning was Letter able to mobilize and all 'cult resources in con- ditions of scarcity. The historical experience of Western Europe and North America, which industrialized in an era of limited government, was not thought to be relevant. Yet the more recent experience of the Third World shows that a dominant government role in developing economies has done more to stifle the natural forces of production and productivity and to distort the efficient allocation of resources. The real engine of growth, in developing as well as industrial- ized countries, turns out to be the natural dynamism of societies that minimize central planning, open themselves to trade with the world, and give free rein to the talents and efforts and risk-taking and investment deci- sions of individuals. Private and State Sector Approaches to Development It is becoming more and more obvious throughout the hemisphere that without a dynamic free enterprise system, governments can neither stimulate nor sustain economic growth nor diversify their economies to foster economic development. Too often in the past, one heard the truism that first must come a proper infrastructure, but this has led to vastly overblown bureaucracies of government-owned means of production far beyond such basic infrastructure re- quirements as roads, utilities, and com- munications. Without an efficient and limited public sector at a manageable economic cost-and without an overall environment conducive to sound in- vestment-privately owned enterprises are unlikely to make their full contribu- tion to development and commerce. Economic development can no longer be financed externally through massive amounts of foreign aid or foreign borrowing, which were hallmarks of the 1960s and 1970s. Nov growth, if it is to come, must begin with each country's climate to attract and keep in country local savings and to at- tract foreign savings, i.e., having a set of motivations and attitudes that are concretely expressed in the absence of civil conflict, a system of generally ac- cepted and enforceable property rights, and the ability of individuals to enjoy the fruits of their labor without confiscatory systems of taxation or arbitrary seizure of property. If government controls too much of the means of production, as is the case in many of the high-debtor countries in our hemisphere, or if it is inefficient and ineffective or all of the above, or if it pursues policies that significantly distort free-market deci- sionmaking, the overall prospects for economic development suffer, and inter- national commerce with it. As Secretary Shultz noted in the testimony I cited earlier: . recent experience has fueled a broad and long-overdue skepticism about statist solutions, central planning, and government directions. This intellectual shift is partly the prod- uct of the extraordinary vigor of the American recovery. The United States has revised its tax system to provide real incen- tives to work, to save, to invest, to take risks, to be efficient. We have reduced government regulation, intervention, and con- trol. We have opened opportunities for freer competition in transportation, finance, com- Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87MOO539ROO0901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 munication, manufacturing, and distribution. Last year's real growth in GNP lcr?ss na- tional product] war d w sharpest inrrea-c since 1951: inflation was the lowest since 1967. The overall result was the creation of over 7 million new jobs in 2 years. It is our sincere hope that the fac- tors behind our present success in the United States will be emulated in Latin America because a return to sound economic policies in all of the hemi- sphere would be mutually beneficial and ultimately create a better standard of living for all. We are all one hemisphere, and what affects the Latin countries af- fects us all. Clearly, it is in my own country's trading interest, since we are running a $20 billion trade deficit with Latin America, largely as a result of its sharply curtailed imports from us. It is also in the interest of the world's finan- cial institutions which have major loan exposures there. Finally, the ability of the hemisphere to withstand communist adventurism and narco-terrorism depends on sound economic policies for economic recovery. As one who has worked with the Latins for 30 years, I don't think I can emphasize strongly enough my feeling that Latin America must work toward a better balance between government and free enterprise, which at present is so heavily skewed toward state ownership. Unfortunately, we seem to be losing the semantic battle for the minds of Latin Americans when we extol the vir- tues of free enterprise. It is an unfor- tunate fact that Marxist teachers have infiltrated primary schools in many Latin American countries. From that key position, they take advantage of their young charges' formative years to make them feel that Marxism is the natural state of affairs of any society. Therefore, anyone who opposes it must be against humanity. Foreign private direct investment becomes "economic im- perialism" in the Marxist-Leninist lex- icon, and this economic imperialism op- poses a "new international economic order" which calls for redistribution of the world's wealth. In the Marxist lex- icon, we are in a zero-sum game where, if one group is to attain greater wealth (read "the exploiters"), another group must lose it. None of this helps to en- courage the much-needed new capital to come in to create the jobs so desperately needed in countries with unemployment levels ranging up to 30% and 40%. In fact, one wonders if Marxists in coun- tries with non-Marxist governments don't hope to keep unemployment levels high, in the hopes that the resulting unrest might help bring them to power. The trend toward government ownership is clearly seen in Mexico, where, according to trend data, there were only 84 government enterprises in 1972. By 1982. there were 760. During the same period, total government spending as a percentage of gross na- tional product increased from 23% to 46%. By 1982, following the bank na- tionalization. the great majority of Mexico's major industries were under government control, and the govern- ment's share of total capital formation had reached 451io. It is an interesting footnote that in the period 1957-72 (dur- ing most of which Dr. Ortiz Mena, now president of the Inter-American Development Bank. was finance minister), Mexico's compound annual rate of GDP [gross domestic product] growth was 6.6%, whereas during the period 1973-83, after the oil boom began, this GDP growth rate averaged 4.7%. Even in Brazil-where in 1979 President Figueiredo created a special ministry with the objectives of (1) selling government-owned enterprises to the private sector. where feasible; (2) restricting the indiscriminate growth of state-owned enterprises; and (3) strengthening the free enterprise system-little progress has been made and the spending of government and its companies approaches 50% of the gross domestic product. A good sign for positive change is that some of the empirical research which has been conducted on the macroeconomic consequences of the statist "solutions" so long favored in most of Latin America is beginning to receive wider publicity and beginning to affect the thinking of high-level policymakers. Ke-Young Chu and An- drew Feltenstein, in their paper "Relative Price Distortions and Inflation: The Case of Argentina, 1963-76" (Inter- national Monetary Fund, Staff Papers, Volume 25, September 1978),-for exam- ple, estimated that, in Argentina, government transfers to cover public enterprises' losses were proportionately 10 times as inflationary as the financing of private enterprises' losses through commercial bank borrowings, primarily because it is assumed that only in the former case are the losses translated in- to high-powered money through central bank financing of the government deficit. Because the state in Argentina owns the vast majority of its industrial production, and since most of these state-owned industries operate at enor- mous losses which only government printing presses can make up, the infla- tion rate there last year approached 700%. Other equally devastating findings are discussed in Public Enterprises in Mixed Economies, by Robert H. Floyd, Clive S. Gray, and R.P. Short: For 25 developing countries for which data were available, Short estimates the average (weighted by GDP) overall public deficit, before reduction by government cur- rent transfers, at 5.5 percent of GDP during the mid-1970s. He further estimates that thc? overall deficit in developing countries in- creased by 2.5 percentage points of GDP be- tween the late 1960s and mid-1970s. Defining the "budgetary burden" of public enterprises as the residual of government transfers and loans, less loan sert ice payments by the enterprises, Short estimates this burden to average 3.3 percent of GDP for 34 developing countries, compared with a 4.4 percent estimate for the central govern- ment's overall budget deficit in these coun- tries. In other words, public enterprises ac- counted for three-fourths of the centrau government deficit in the countries in question. As I have witnessed during the last 30 years, the Latin American countries have suffered ever more stifling bureaucratization of their economies. Government intervention-often but- tressed by nationalist and/or socialist ideologies-has resulted in substantial increases in: ? State ownership of economic ac- tivities in, for example, extractive in- dustries, manufacturing, financing, and international trade and commerce, far beyond the traditional limits of in- frastructure and often accomplished through expropriation without adequate compensation; ? Regulation of private economic ac- tivity via money, credit, and exchange controls, licensing systems, and price and wage controls; ? The state's consumption share of gross national product; and ? Government investment expen- diture-typically more than half of na- tional capital formation. Informal Economy In spite of these trends, which amount to a fight for survival on the part Of free enterprise in many parts of Latin America, there are several count--r- trends. A good example of how the private sector can triumph in spit.' of governmental restrictions is revealed in the study by Peruvian businessman a nl economist Hernando de Soto. Because it takes a person 6 months to get gott?rn- ment approval to set up a simple business in Peru, an informal eeon-'i!iic system has grown to rival the 111111'r traditional business. According Soto, an informal economy developer: Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 and grew despite the tremendous hand- icap of being illegal. De Soto's study estimates that the informal economy of Peru now accounts for 90% of Lima's garment industry, 25% of its furniture industry, 60% of housing construction, and even a good part of the automobile and truck in- dustries. The informal Peruvian economy, says the study, has grown so fast that it now accounts for an estimated 60% of the total Peruvian economy, and almost none of this output is counted in the official $22 billion Peru- vian gross domestic product. Perhaps most important is the free enterprise system's ability to create jobs: in Peru, an estimated two out of every three jobs are now in the informal sector. Another factor Mr. de Soto's study points out is that South American economies often have two kinds of private sectors: one that is seriously burdened by excessive regulation and hampered by bureaucratic inefficiency but is officially sanctioned, and a second one which is far more in accord with free market principles but whose ex- istence is barely acknowledged. This dif- ference is made clear by an experiment documented by a study group from Mr. de Soto's Institute for Liberty and Democracy, in which it tried to set up a legal garment firm without easing the way with bribes. According to a Wall Street Journal article: It took a lawyer and three others 301 days of full-time work, dealing with 11 government agencies to complete the paper- work-which, when laid end-to-end, measured 102 feet. (One of the researchers then tried the same experiment in Tampa, Florida, and finished it in 31h hours.) Debt Crisis Management As we all know, Mexico's extreme illi- quidity in August of 1982 precipitated the "debt crisis." The response was a provision of immediate emergency assistance by the U.S. Government and other creditors which led to the develop- ment of a rescue package and an IMF [International Monetary Fund] stabiliza- tion program. By the spring of 1983, the U.S. Government had developed a strategy designed to deal with the li- quidity problems, primarily of the major countries, and to encourage the adoption of needed stabilization measures. What has not been widely understood is that the strategy was not intended to be one of "solution" for the "debt crisis" but rather one of "management" of the crisis with the central purpose of preventing the liquidity problems from developing into a crisis of the entire international financing system. I think it would be helpful to recall the elements of the U.S. Government strategy for management of the debt crisis as reaffirmed at the Williamsburg summit: ? Credible economic stabilization measures to be undertaken by the in- dividual debtor countries; ? Sustainable economic growth in the OECD [Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development] coun- tries, combined with the maintenance of open markets; ? Support from the IMF and other international financial institutions for economic adjustment; and ? The provision of bridge financing by creditor governments when needed. I think we can all agree that, up to now, the strategy has succeeded in its central purpose of avoiding the develop- ment of a systemic crisis while, at the same time, supporting stabilization ef- forts in the debtor countries. Not Yet Out of the Woods I believe that, with what I have said up to this point, it should be clear that we are not out of the woods. In fact, I would agree with the testimony of Dr. Norman Bailey, former Assistant to the President for International Economic Affairs, before the Subcommittee on Western Hemisphere Affairs of the U.S. House of Representatives on January 29, 1985: "... Unfortunately, we have always been in the woods and the path out of them is obscure and easily lost." Agreement with this statement stems not from an attitude of pessimism but rather from an acute recognition that the real world is pregnant with danger-the economists' definition of the real world being "the nominal world minus inflation" notwithstanding. One is led to this opinion by simple arithmetic. At the end of 1981, the Latin American countries owed approximately $297 billion. At the end of 1984, their external indebtedness amounted to about $371 billion. Despite the high visibility of U.S. banks in this situation, they, nevertheless, only hold one-fourth of this debt, the rest being held by foreign banks, multilateral lending in- stitutions, and governments. After 3 years of crisis and austerity, Latin America, therefore, has increased its in- debtedness by about $75 billion on which, by the way, interest is due. About $34 billion of the $75 billion was lent by commercial banks in countries reporting to the Bank for International Settlements, and of the $34 billion, $12.6 billion was lent by U.S. banks. During the period 1981-84, as a result of rescheduling agreements, the debt ser- vice ratio-i.e., interest and principle payments as a percentage of foreign ex- change earnings (export earnings from goods and services)-of the debtor coun- tries declined from 51.2% to 43.3% of merchandise exports. The ratio of net in- terest payments to merchandise exports declined somewhat to about 35% in 1984, demonstrating the sensitivity of these economies to both export growth and the changes in world interest rates. From the point of view of the balance of payments, we have seen Latin America accumulate a $74 billion merchandise trade surplus in the period 1982-84 inclusive, but one which is ap- parently largely due to tremendous cuts in imports. The most recent estimates indicate that the value of Latin American exports in 1984 was still somewhat below 1981, although export volume showed an increase. During the same 3-year period, debt service pay- ments amounted to $109 billion, and new money and the surplus on the trade balance amounted to about $148 billion, which I read to mean that approximate- ly $39 billion was spent on services, fled the region, or was added to international reserves. Even under optimistic assump- tions, the World Bank, the Inter- American Development Bank, and others have concluded that it will be the end of the decade before 1980 pre- recession per capita levels of gross domestic product will again be achieved. Major Uncertainties There remain a number of major uncer- tainties which render the global economic environment pregnant with danger. Highest on my list of uncertain- ties is the debt crisis, where we are by no means out of the woods, despite a re- cent spate of news articles to the con- trary. One fact which is often overlooked is that the country with the largest exter- nal debt in the world is not Brazil or Argentina, it is the United States of America. By the end of June last year, foreigners had lent our treasury $171 billion, which was 15.6% of the total. The foreign debt of the American private sector at the end of June 1984 was estimated to be another $299 billion. It has been estimated that, by the end of May this year, the United States will become a net international debtor for the first time since shortly before World War I. Perhaps, when we bemoan the international "debt crisis," we should remember the words of John Donne: "Ask not for whom the bell tolls, it tolls for thee." Nevertheless, the size and Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 growth of our economy, coupled with positive encouragement of free enter- prise by President Reagan's policies, give us grounds for more optimism than in those countries where the parastatal, government intervention model predominates. With regard to international debt prospects, Assistant Secretary of State for Economic and Business Affairs Richard T. McCormack posed two ques- tions in a speech delivered last November ("The Medium-Term Outlook for the World-Economy," Novem- ber 22, 1984, Current Policy No. 664): First, is our [worldwide] present success in reducing these [balance-of-payments] deficits based on a draconian depression of activity ... that is not sustainable either socially or politically? Second, is the present outlook viable only under the most favorable assumptions and vulnerable to new shocks, such as OECD recession or higher interest rates? Solutions I believe these questions remain valid, but for these questions to be given favorable answers in a historical sense, the "debt crisis" must be genuinely resolved. And for a genuinely favorable resolution, the solution must be sought in the reform of the domestic economies of the debtor countries of the hemisphere themselves. The economic policies necessary to achieve such a reform are relatively easy to summarize. In terms of monetary policy, there must exist positive inflation-adjusted interest rates, realistic exchange rates, economically sound measures to control inflationary pressures, and measures to induce the return of flight capital. In terms of fiscal policy, the governments of our Latin American neighbors must rein in parastatal enterprises-which, for the most part, are deficit-ridden and a major source of inflation-reform their taxa- tion and tax collection systems, and reduce subsidies. Simply put, they must put their own houses in order by creating clear and stable rules of the game for economic activity-clear rules which encourage productive activity by offering a secure climate for investment, both domestic and foreign. What is needed was succinctly de- fined by Secretary of State George P. Shultz in his address of December 6, 1984, entitled: "Democracy and the Path to Economic Growth" [Current Policy No. 641). i am calling here for the reversal of state ownership and anti-import policies. These policies have placed stifling controls on private agriculture and industry. They have made them dependent on restricted markets. They have built costly protectionist barriers at national 'frontiers. And they have produced inefficient state enterprises that divert resources from more productive activities. I call, instead, for a development strategy that works through an open economy, one that rewards initiative, investment, and thrift. Maintaining an Open Multilateral Trading System The world economy continues to be involved in a process of adjustment. Simply put, this adjustment involves converging the levels of consumption and production. During the 1970s, many countries lived beyond their means, as reflected in their unsustainable balance- of-payment positions. This situation must now be corrected by either increas- ing the "means" or living more modestly or both. While this process is not cost free, it is inevitable and has as its ultimate goal the restoration of sus- tainable noninflationary global economic growth. A key element in this adjustment process is the maintenance of an open multilateral trading system, which is essential to position the countries of the hemisphere for servicing their external debt and for enabling the export and im- port sectors of all our economies to make their contributions to domestic economic recovery and growth. I also want to make three further points. First, protectionism poses a serious threat to the prospects for a medium- term recovery in the world economy. Virtually all economic projections are predicated on open trade. If the assump- tion about the maintenance of open trading policies is removed, the medium- term outlook for the world economy becomes bleak. Second, protectionism poses a fun- damental threat to the.strategy that has fostered development since 1945. Inter- national trade is a powerful engine of growth. The experience of the 1960s and 1970s demonstrated that countries with "inward-looking" development strate- gies-characterized by liberal import regimes, adequate incentives for pro- ducers, and the maintenance of realistic exchange rates and prices as well as positive real interest rates-have per- formed better than countries with "outward-looking" development strategies. Protectionism would threaten the viability of the "outward-looking" strategies with far-reaching conse- quences for economic efficiency and world trade. The postwar strategy in many Latin countries of industrializing through im- port substitution, with its high tariff barriers, has been disappointing. It has fostered dual economies, crippled development in the agricultural sector, resulted in frequent balance-of-payments crises, and contributed to rapid urban growth and political instability. Studies by the OECD and the World Bank both recognize that a substantial relaxation of import restrictions coupled with moves toward appropriate exchange rates are necessary to expand exports and over- come the shortage of foreign exchange that most developing countries (except for some of the oil exporters) seem to face. It should not come as a surprise that the development strategies based on im- port substitution have produced such poor results. Import substitution carried to excess is a little like a soccer team that plays only itself. Competition hones the skills and tactics of a soccer team, and, by definition, Brazil could never have won the world soccer championship if it had not been willing to play against foreign teams. Moreover, import substitution policies often also violate the law of comparative advantage since they amount to a dirigiste attempt to outguess the marketplace. For these reasons, developing coun- tries are urged to use great caution in applying import-substitution measures, and such countries are encouraged to focus more actively on the possibilities which exports offer their economies, while striving to keep our markets open to those exports. Since the 1970s, many of the more successful developing coun- tries have been pursuing precisely such a strategy. The economic success stories, such as Taiwan, South Korea, and Singapore, have all adopted policies which emphasize exports as a means of promoting rapid industrialization. In recent years, these and other countries have shifted toward more liberal trade and payment regimens. Often, these moves have not been as rapid nor as encompassing as we might want. But overall, particularly in East and Southeast Asia, there has been a clear tendency of the more economically progressive and successful countries to move in the direction of liberalizing trade barriers and adopting policies aimed at stimulating exports. The U.S. Mission to the OAS has recently chaired meetings of the ambassadors of the ASEAN [Association of South East Asian Nations] countries with the An- dean OAS ambassadors, with the thought that fellow "developing coun- tries" along the Pacific rim might corn- Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 pare notes so that the most successful features of each economic system might be examined. Third, protectionism is, by defini- tion, "anti-adjustment." It is an ad- ministrative way of delaying adjustment to changes in competitive positions stem- ming from changes in technology and productivity. We must jointly and severally rise to the challenge of struc- tural adjustment rather than run away from it. Renewed growth and the reinvigoration of all our economies demand it. I would like to note here that the U.S. commitment to an open multilateral trading system remains firm. as was demonstrated yet again in President Reagan's call for a new round of trade negotiations under the GATT [General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade] in his State of the Union Address. It has been contended that no country has an entire- ly open system. In this imperfect world, however, the United States is still the most open market among the major trading nations, as witnessed by our re- cent horrendous trade deficits. What is needed in the new trade round is a rededication to work toward perfecting the multilateral trading systems so that opportunities for fair trade can be in- creased for all participants. By fair, we mean that the goal posts should be the same width for each side. If ours is 20 feet wide and our trading partner wants his to be only 2 feet, we're going to lose a lot of games, and nobody believes that's fair. Vast Capital Needs Latin America still needs vast amounts of capital for progress or, indeed, to maintain present living standards. Ac- cording to an Inter-American Develop- ment Bank study, between now and the year 2000, Latin America and the Carib- bean will have to create 100 million new jobs, since half of the population is under 20, and birth rates are running at 3% (with Mexico's at 5.8%). The average cost for creating one new job in the region is estimated at $12,500, leading to an approximation that $1.25 trillion in capital will have to be generated in the next 15 years-a figure perhaps twice the amount of all transfers of funds to the hemisphere in the past 15 years, which includes the huge borrowing splurge of the 1970s. For Latin America, if the decade of the 1960s can be considered as the decade of official aid from the developed countries (including the Alliance for Progress) and the decade of the 1970s as the decade of commercial bank lending (nearly $300 billion), then the decade of tional Investment So Small?," made the the 1980s must be the decade of foreign following comments: direct investment.-Why? Because, re- garding future prospects for official aid, it would be prudent not to expect that support via the International Monetary Fund, the World Bank, and other multi- lateral lending institutions will be a re- placement for private sector lending- and I stress the word replacement-for a number of reasons. First, the sums needed are simply too large. Second, virtually all industrialized country governments, including that of the United States, are grappling with the issue of controlling their own government deficits. Third, it is unlikely that industrial- ized country central banks will be as ac- commodating toward these deficits as they were in the 1970s. Further, it is now widely recognized that Latin America will not receive even remotely the same high level of bor- rowed capital from the banking systems to which it became accustomed during the 1970s, particularly in light of debt servicing problems on existing loans. Of course, borrowing is only one of the three types of international mone- tary transfers-the other two being direct aid, either government-to-govern- ment or multilateral, and foreign direct investment. It is obvious to all that foreign direct investment, if it can be gotten, has the advantage over the other two of providing management know- how, technical skills, and technology transfers resulting in a high degree of export potential and, therefore, of being a source for valuable foreign exchange. There seems little doubt that substantial capital exports have taken place from the countries that were borrowing. Unfortunate- ly, one must assume that in large part this represents capital flight. The assets, thus ac- quired, probably do not produce income and taxes from the capital-exporting country, and probably are not available to strengthen its foreign exchange position and its economy generally. In other words, given economic and political conditions of the capital- exporting countries, these foreign assets are not likely to play the same constructive role for the home countries that capital exports from developed countries have ordinarily played. To be sure, changes in the politics and economic policies of the respective coun- tries, giving adequate protection to the owners of capital and a positive real return on domestic assets, may change that situa- tion. They may convert what today is flight capital into an important resource for the country. The irony of this situation is that, in fact, Latin Americans own plenty of capital. It is just not located inside Latin America-the amounts in Swiss and Miami banks and in San Diego con- dominiums probably far exceed the li- quid funds in the home countries. In- deed, generations of Latins claim they have been brought up to get their money out into "safer" havens as soon as they make it. This trend has to be reversed if Latin America is to grow at all. Henry Wallich further states: For the [world's] eight largest [non-U.S.] borrowers over the years 1974-1982.... calculation[s] show an increase in debt (equity and direct investment included) of $317 billion, while the current account deficit ad- justed for changes in official reserves, amounts to only $207 billion. Thus, there needed capital-in competition with seems to have been a capital outflow of $110 billion. The degree to which borrowing other countries also aggressively seeking financed this capital outflow differs among it, such as members of the OECD and countries. For Brazil, only 12 percent of the the Pacific Basin countries-the climate inflow was compensated by outflows; for for investment must be much more con- ducive in Latin America. The best test of this is found where local investors themselves find it attractive to reinvest their own funds and where there is no capital flight. Capital Flight Just at the time when Latin America needs so much more new capital, there has been the reverse trend of hemor- rhaging capital outflows through flight capital. Henry C. Wallich, member of the Board of Governors of the U.S. Federal Reserve System, in a recent incisive paper entitled, "Why is Net Interna- Mexico, 45 percent; for Venezuela, almost the entire inflow was absorbed into outflows. Nearly 100% capital flight? Clearly, with a change in domestic policies away from the parastatal-import substitution approach to economic development, there is reason to believe that this money could be attracted back to Latin America, which would, of course, be a major contribution to a lasting solution of the debt crisis and job creation. In his February 8, 1985, address, "The International Debt Situation in an American View: Borrowing Countries and Lending Banks," Henry C. Wallich states further: Unfortunately, one must assume that a large part of the borrowed money went for consumption, in the form of excessive im- Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 ports of high-priced oil and various consumer goods. Frequently this spending was financed through government budget deficits, caused by subsidies and other unproductive expen- ditures. including purchase of weapons. A worldwide shift from negative real interest rates to significantly positive real rates, and the consequent rise in debt service, also used up some of the funds borrowed. In adding up incremental investment, capital flight, and increased outlays (in nominal terms) for consumption, there is a danger of over-explaining the absorption of borrowed funds. The best judgment seems to be that the borrowing countries experienced a substantial increase in their income and debt-carrying capacity and that these benefits of added investment could be enhanced in future, if measures are taken to induce flight capital to return. It may be that this audience will find itself closer to the Henry Wallich school of thought on flight capital than the point of view expressed to me recently by a prominent Argentine economist that, at least in the Argentine case, the term "flight capital" was misleading and that more accurate terminology would be "portfolio diversification." Other Solutions While it is relatively easy to diagnose the ills resulting from excessive govern- mental involvement in our economies, it is far more difficult to find constructive solutions. In many of the countries of our hemisphere, the state-owned sector is so large, relative to the domestically owned pool of private capital, that a simple sale of those state enterprises that are running the largest deficits would be difficult (who would want to buy them?), and attracting foreign capital for this purpose also would be difficult, for well-known political reasons. Indeed, there are still many in Latin America who would view selling off parastatals to "transnationals" in the same way as they view foreign direct in- vestment-selling off their "national patrimony." There have been ideas floated that some debt could be ex- changed for equity in the parastatals. Brazil considered this for a time, but may have given up on the idea, at least for the present. However, I believe that there are other potential and feasible solutions over the long term, for, as President Reagan has said, 'Developing countries need to be encouraged to experiment with the growing variety of arrange- ments for profit-sharing and expanded capital ownership that can bring economic betterment to their people." One such method of expanded capital ownership is advocated by Dr. Louis 0. Kelso and Patricia Hetter in their book, La Economia de los Dos Factores: Un Tercer Camino. The plan involves employee stock ownership plans, which are nothing less than having the employees of the corporation also become the stockholders, i.e., owners. There are now approximately 8,000 cor- porations in the United States using these plans, and the experience with them has been quite good-productivity goes up, worker income is linked to profitability, etc. While they are only one form of expanded capital ownership, the point I am trying to make is that there are alternatives to state owner- ship, and they should be explored and adapted to the conditions existing in each of the countries of our hemisphere. Indeed, Costa Rica and Guatemala have rapidly increasing employee stock ownership plans. But the benefits of expanded capital ownership go far beyond the economic, as has recently been demonstrated in the La Perla project in Guatemala. La Perla is a 9,000-acre coffee and car- damom plantation in northern Guate- mala. It has 500 full-time employees, about 1,500 family members, and ap- proximately 4,000 other people depen- dent on the economy of the estate. In September 1984, the farm's owners set up a trust in which they allocated 40% of the stock. The stock will be paid for out of the future profits of the farm, but upon the signing, full voting rights were passed through to an employee associa- tion. Early this year, 120 insurgents at- tacked the estate and actually took con- trol of the center. The insurgents, however, were then attacked and driven off the farm by 200 armed workers, and a number of workers and insurgents were killed. In the week following the attack, the estate's 300 unarmed worker-owners petitioned the owners for additional rifles to defend against future insurgent attacks and volunteered to help pay for them through a payroll deduction plan. As Joseph Recinos (a representative of the Solidarity Union of Guatemala, a movement aimed at ex- panded capital ownership as a means of economic and social reform), has stated: We can more clearly see what the true message of ownership and of vested interest in the free enterprise system means in view- ing the La Perla model. There is no greater significance to the concept of defending the free enterprise system than a worker laying down his life to defend the company in which he is co-owner. If we want to prevent further Nicaraguas or El Salvadors, the American Government must address the problem of economic and social justice in Central America. Promoting broad capital ownership as an alternative to Marxist philosophy in Latin America, if they are actively pushed now as foreign policy ob- jectives, can go a long way in giving people a vested interest in protecting the free- enterprise system. Norman Kurland, one of the founders of the Center for Economic and Social Justice (a group whose goal is the promotion of employee stock owner- ship plans) stated in a Washington Ti7nes interview last September: To win over Marxism-Leninism you have to go beyond the military. Of course, you have to be militarily strong. On the other hand, there is an ideological battle. Marx and Engels stated that you could sum up the en- tire philosophy of communism in a single sentence: Abolish private property. The entire case of Marxism-Leninism disappears if we prove to the world that private property is essential for providing economic and social justice, and for providing human dignity to people in the Third V1'urld. Marx was wrong. However, we cannot simply attack him on the basis of the prob- lems he was focusing on but rather on the basis of the means that he would use. The solution is not to make enemies of the owners but to make owners out of the nonowners. Foreign Direct Investment Over the past 4 years, it has been made clear to me, in visits to every country in the hemisphere, that private foreign direct investment can play the key role in future trade and commerce. Indeed, it is the catalyst for economic development and international economic integration through the world trading system, as well as being perhaps the only remaining source of capital, technology, and management know-how on a scale needed for economic survival. It seems intuitively obvious that the high-debtor countries of our hemisphere must take strong steps to court foreign direct investment as the most attractive alternative to new bank financing. Foreign direct investment has the ad- vantage of not requiring fixed interest payments. Earnings are repatriated only if the investment is profitable. Local enterprises are able to sell to multina- tional companies and often gain access to new markets and distribution chan- nels, both nationally and internationally. Finally, and most importantly, foreign direct investment creates real jobs as opposed to state-funded make-work jobs. Unfortunately, the trend has been in the other direction. In 1950, U.S. direct investment in Latin America accounted for nearly 50% of the total U.S. invest- ment overseas. By 1970, this figure had dropped 17% in Latin America and was 8% in Asia and the Pacific. At the end of 1982, the stock of U.S. direct invest- Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 ment was down 15% in Latin America and had doubled to 6% in Asia and the Pacific. In a time when total flows of U.S. foreign investment were declining. flows to the Far East rose sharply. I am encouraged by the increasing recognition of the importance of internal factors for the revitalization of Latin American economies now being ex- pressed by prominent Latin Americans. Brazilian Senator and former Planning and Finance Minister Roberto Campos stated the issues succinctly in his speech, "The New Demonology": "The United States has become the magnet for Euro- pean and Japanese investors precisely because they have two things we lack-a strong currency and stable rules of the game." The prominent Argentine economist, Marcos Victorica, has also addressed these issues. Alr. Victorica estimates that Argentine capital abroad amounts to about $27 billion and that much of this capital left the country during the early 1980s, despite the fact that real in- terest rates in Argentina amounted to about 20%o-double U.S. real interest rates-and he has ascribed these devel- opments to a lack of confidence. Regard- ing policies affecting foreign direct in- vestment, Mr. Victorica has noted one of the key difficulties (such as exchange controls): "No one will come in [to in- vest] where a way out is forbidden." Argentine Presidential Secretary General German Lopez recently spotlighted this problem in comments reported on the Buenos Aires govern- ment radio network, when he stated that, "President Alfonsin is determined to modernize the country and that, to this end, there is no alternative but to resort to foreign capital so that the in- vestments that will contribute to Argen- tine development are made." The only way to make up for the time lost, Lopez states, is to urgently attract invest- ments, adding that: I want to say that the past 10 years have been very dramatic for Argentina and that I consider that in reviewing, in weighing our responsibilities, we are sometimes unfair. We have made mistake after mistake for vir- tually 50 years. We have practiced a sort of political cannibalism destroying each other. [Therefore] President Alfonsin is firmly de- termined to modernize Argentina in order to put it at the level of efficiency asked by public opinion. Recently, the newly elected Presi- dent of Uruguay, Julio Maria Sanguinet- ti, said that "those of us who historically defended a greater role for the State now have to say that we must reestablish equilibrium and that as a result our direction will be to reduce to the maximum extent expenditures of the State, and to encourage as much as we can private production." I am pleased to see that some leaders of Andean Pact countries are taking a new look at their investment policies. During his recent visit to the United States, President Belisario Betancur of Colombia addressed a number of our business leaders on April 2. He said: The Latin American experience of the past 10 years shows that self-sustained development is not stable if it is mainly dependent on a growing foreign debt. The development effort should be based on domestic savings and productive investment, supplemented by foreign loans.... From these considerations you may well understand why I said that ... it was better to have more partners and fewer creditors. We have made a proposal to the member countries of the Cartagena agreement to modify Decision 24 providing more flexible terms in keeping with foreign investment needs. The idea is to allow new investment in certain areas to be 100% foreign when the recipient country decides that its develop- ment needs so warrant. It is now generally recognized by potential investors that one of the dif- ficult impediments to foreign investment in Latin America has been the Calvo Doctrine. Many countries in the hemisphere incorporate the doctrine and other restrictions in their constitutions, in other laws, or in multilateral agreements, such as the Andean Pact decision 24. With regard to decision 24, I am pleased to note that there is in- creasing recognition on the part of member governments of the pact that more flexibility is required by member governments on foreign investment policies. This was one of the principal causes for Chile's withdrawal from the pact in 1976. Moreover, under the dynamic leadership of Craig Nalen, the Overseas Private Investment Corpora- tion (OPIC) recently signed agreements with Colombia and Ecuador. These agreements were the result of countless hours of patient and persistent negotia- tion between Lorin S. Weisenfeld, Assistant General Counsel of OPIC, and various officials of Colombia and Ecuador, and it is to be hoped that other Andean Pact countries will follow. While the United States rejects the Calvo Doctrine on the theory that the in- vestor's government has an independent interest in fair treatment for its na- tionals, the Calvo Doctrine has unques- tionably had a negative impact on the ability of foreign governments to pro- vide diplomatic protection in the event of a miscarriage of justice. This doctrine had its origin in the early part of this century as a reaction to perceived abuses of protection by the United States and European powers on behalf of their investors and traders in the last century. In countries that subscribe to the Calvo Doctrine, the foreign investor is considered to have agreed that all disputes-including those relating to ex- propriation-will be definitively resolved through local legal processes, and to have renounced any right to invoke the diplomatic protection of his home government in the event those processes give rise to a miscarriage of justice following expropriation. In the 1960s and 1970s, there were over 300 major expropriations in the hemisphere (ex- cluding the $1.85 billion in thousands of unsettled expropriation claims of former U.S. investors in Cuba) where compen- sation was not arrived at through inter- national arbitration and was often gross- ly inadequate or delayed in many cases. Corporate boardrooms around the world have long corporate memories, and as Cicero said to Atticus, "It is the right given to any man to err, but to no one, unless he is a fool, to persist in." Another negative consequence of this policy is that potential U.S. in- vestors are constrained from obtaining OPIC insurance coverage because of re- quirements limiting possible litigation to local courts, and of a prohibition of direct subrogation. The United States has long favored an open international investment system. A major U.S. goal in the 1980s is to reverse the trend toward govern- ment-induced distortions in the invest- ment process through international understandings and voluntary guidelines leading to a more open investment climate in which investment flows are able to respond to market forces. Recent Positive Steps As part of continuing efforts in this area, the U.S. delegation to the 14th an- nual General Assembly of the OAS in- troduced a resolution entitled "Pro- moting Ecomonic Justice Through Strengthening Private Direct and In- direct Investment in Latin America and the Caribbean." The operative part of the resolution reads as follows: To instruct the General Secretariat to conduct a study of requirements necessary for the creation of economic and regulatory environments conducive to attracting and fostering direct and indirect investment in the countries of Latin America and the Carib- bean. This study should identify the various private and official, multilateral and national agencies involved in the promotion of invest- ment while also considering and evaluating Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8 - the growing variety of arrangements for profit-sharing and expanded capital owner- ship now available for the promotion of economic justice with a view to identifying operational mechanisms and sources of fund- ing for cooperative efforts with said agencies that may be implemented in the framework of the OAS. While the resolution did not come to a formal vote, the U.S. delegation was able to secure agreement, as noted in the rapporteur's report, that these topics would be taken up by the Permanent Executive Committee of the Inter- American Economic and Social Commit- tee of the OAS in 1985. I view this agreement as a major achievement and a major step forward for Latin America, not because U.S., Japanese, or other OECD investors have any shortage of opportunities to invest at home or abroad, but because of the potential benefits to our own hemisphere that foreign direct investment brings in terms of improving standards of living. The Reagan Administration is ac- tively pursuing two programs in Central and South America which aim to im- prove the investment climate: the Carib- bean Basin Initiative (CBI) and bilateral investment treaties. The CBI, by grant- ing various products access to the U.S. market, provides important incentives for the private sector. Bilateral invest- ment treaties offer important protection for investments. The intent of both pro- grams is to stimulate additional foreign investment. As you know, the key elements of the bilateral investment treaties are: ? New and existing investment to be granted national treatment or most- Bureau of Public Affairs United States Department of State Washington, D.C. 20520 If address is incorrect phase indicate change. Do not cover or destroy this address label. Mail change of address to: PA/OAP, Rm. 5515A favored-nation treatment, whichever is more favorable, but both sides are allowed to list exceptions to national treatment in specified sectors of economic activity; ? Conditions for expropriation which accord with international law principles, including payment of prompt, adequate, and effective compensation; ? Unrestricted transfer of capital, returns, compensation, and other payments into and out of the host coun- try; and ? Dispute settlement procedures in- volving third-party arbitration both for disputes between the host country and a national or company of the other coun- try and disputes arising between the governments. While these treaties are generally reciprocal in their provisions, the major inducement for the developing country is the assurances such a treaty offers a foreign investor. As a result of the leadership of Bill Brock of USTR [U.S. Trade Represen. tative], several countries have nego- tiated such agreements with us. In this hemisphere, we signed treaties with Panama in 1982 and with Haiti in December 1983. We are also very close to agreement with Costa Rica, and we have had negotiations with Honduras and El Salvador. While the treaties mentioned above are laudable achievements for the par- ties concerned, in all candor, much re- mains to be done for our hemisphere to realize its full economic potential. Conclusion I titled my remarks today, "Free Enter- prise: Key to Latin American Economic Revival." I would like to end on a positive note. Simon Bolivar said 150 years ago that Bolivia was a beggar sit- ting on a throne of gold. In an expanded sense, this is still true for resource-rich but extremely poor Bolivia and for several other countries in Latin America. The hemisphere is so rich in natural resources and populated by men and women of such talent and good will that there is no reason that our hemisphere cannot have a bright economic future. All that is needed is for the economic and political leadership of Latin America to reembrace the wisdom of their own founding fathers, Simon Bolivar and San Martin. These men of vision, along with our own Founding Fathers, were swept up with the liberalizing writings of Locke, Rousseau, Hume, and Adam Smith, which called for a separation of political and economic power and emphasized the sanctity of private property. Similar wisdom can be found in the words of Muhammad Ibn Khaldoun, the 14th cen- tury Arab jurist, historian, and statesman: "When incentive to acquire and obtain property is gone, people no longer make efforts to acquire any. This leads to destruction and ruin of civilization." ^ Published by the United States Department of State ? Bureau of Public Affairs Office of Public Communication - Editorial Division ? Washington, D.C. ? May 1985 Editor. Cynthia Saboe - This material is in the public domain and may be reproduced without permission; citation of this source is appreciated. Postage and Fees Paid Department of State STA-501 Sanitized Copy Approved for Release 2010/02/24: CIA-RDP87M00539R000901220007-8