POSTWAR ECONOMIC GROWTH IN EASTERN EUROPE- A COMPARISON WITH WESTERN EUROPE

Document Type: 
Collection: 
Document Number (FOIA) /ESDN (CREST): 
CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3
Release Decision: 
RIPPUB
Original Classification: 
K
Document Page Count: 
99
Document Creation Date: 
December 9, 2016
Document Release Date: 
March 21, 2001
Sequence Number: 
1
Case Number: 
Content Type: 
REPORT
File: 
AttachmentSize
PDF icon CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3.pdf3.97 MB
Body: 
.. ~v,,, Approved For Release 2001/04/12 :CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 i ~7~G G - ~s i ~, ~~os~ POSTWAR ECONOMIC GROWTH IN EASTERN EUROPE- A Comparison with Western Europe STATINTL by Approved For Release 2001/04/12 :CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Postwar Economic Growth in Eastern E4.irope I. Characteristics of the Eastern European Economies II. Statistics and Methods III. Growth of Production ~+ 8 12 A. Gross National product 12 B. Pattern of Economic growth 17 1. Industrial production 17 2. Agricultural production 20 3. Services 21 IV. Trends in Consumption and Consumer Welfare 21 V. Cost of Economic Growth 32 A. Volume and distribution of investment 32 B. Productivity of investment 35 C. Factors in investment costs 38 1. Labor inputs 38 2. Sectoral and branch distribution of investment 42 3.Replacement and maintenance of fixed assets ~-3 ~+. Other factors affecting investment costs 45 VI. External factors 52 A. Statistical evidence 52 1. Trends in the volume of imports 52 2. Foreign aid and impositions 56 3. Net terms of trade 60 B. Evaluation 63 VII. Internal and External Policies and Reforms 68 A. Economic reform ~ 69 B. International cooperation and foreign assistance 73 1. Intra-bloc economic cooperation ~ 73 2. Soviet-East European economic relations 7~+ 3. Economic relations with the West 76 Appendix A International Comparisons of Economic Levels Appendix B Measurement of Economic Growth Appendix C Foreign 'T`rade Statistics - 80 84 91 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12 :CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12 :CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 POSTWAR ECONOMIC GROWTH IN EASTERN EUROPE- A Comparison with Western Europe ~.is paper uses comparisons with Western Europe to evaluate postwar economic gro~-th in Eastern Europe. Three main aspects of comparative economic growth are examined: the growth of production; the increase in personal consumption; and the efficiency in the use of inputs. In addition, the relative influence of external factors on economic growth in the two areas is considered. The method of analysis is statistical-- a. comparison of various measures of economic growth and of the measurable factors which may have influenced this growth. Its purpose, however, is to provide evidence on a very intangible question -- the relative performance of the market=type economic system of Western Europe and of the Soviet-type "command-economy" of Eastern Europe. An evaluation of economic .performance founded on international comparisons can be highly artificial since governments or populations may set for themselves standards for growth or efficiency that differ greatly from those of other countries. In the case of Eastern and Western Europe, however, both history and geography give inter-country comparisons considerable importance for national governments and stimulate people to . look across the border for standards of consumption. Moreover, even in the absence of direct comparisons and influence, technological and sociological trends on both sides of the border tend to be .similar enougk~ to make international comparisons meaningL'u1. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 The comparison in this study is limited to 6 Eastern European countries -- Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, East Germany, Hungary, Poland, and Rumania -- and 9 Western European countries -- Austria, Belgium, Denmark, West Germany, France, Greece, Italy, Netherlands, and Norway. The selection was based partly on the availability of appropriate statistics -- which. excluded such countries as Albania and Spaino A second criterion was a reasonable .degree of similarity in economic system among the two groups, which excluded Yugoslavia because its system is a blend of state planning, decentralized state administration, and the market mechanism. A third criterion was to include only countries which met either defeat or occupation during World War II and thus suffered some economic retardation. For many reasons - some evident, some subtle, and some that are not yet clear -- victors, such as the United Kingdom and neutrals, such as Sweden, have had a very different pattern of growth than the defeated or occupied countries. They emerged from the war with increased production-and have since tended to grow more slowly. Im.e main statistical findings of this study are the following: (1~ Over the postwar period as a whole, the growth of production has been rapid in Eastern Europe, but no more so than in Western Europe. In recent years it has been slower in Eastern Europe than in Western Europe. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RD~79T01049A003200110001-3 ? Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 (2) The improvement in per capita consumption and probably also in general consumer_~ welfare has been much smaller in Eastern Europe than in Western Europe. ? (3) By all statistical indications, economic growth has been less efficient in Eastern than in Western Europe -- it has taken larger investment expenditures to obtain similar rates of growth. Lower efficiency, indeed, is a major cause of the relatively slow rise in consumption in Eastern Europe. (~+) Soviet exploitation of Eastern Europe, in contrast to large U.S. aid to Western Europe probably was responsible for the slower recovery of the Eastern European economies after World War II, but neither this factor, nor the trends in the volume and terms of trade can explain the lower postwar ? efficiency of the Eastern European economies. The conclusion from this statistical evidence is that the operation of the Soviet-type economic system in Eastern Europe -- that is, the interrelated set of economic policies and institutions patterned after those of the USSR -- is mainly to blame for this relatively poor performance. These policies and institutions embrace among other things the methods and principles of detailed state planning, the method of economic administration through a vast state bureaucracy, the relegation of the market mechanism to a minor role, and the collectivization of agriculture. The internal and external effects of this "system" are inseparable. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 I. Characteristics of the Eastern European Economies Excluding East Germany and the Bohomia-Moravia section of Czechoslovakia, which historically have been part of .Central Europe, Eastern Europe has always been a relatively undeveloped region. Before World War II agriculture was the predominant economic activity, although there were islands of urban and industrial development. Peasants, by and large, were poor, eating mainly self-produced crops and buying little besides the most essential items. 'I`he industrial workers were much better off than the peasants, but there were few industrial jobs. In Poland, Rumania and Bulgaria, more people were employed in handicraft shops than in factories. Outside East Germany and Czechoslovakia, the main industries were textiles, leather and food processing (throughout the area), coal mining (Poland), . mining oil extraction (mainly in Rumania), bauxite~(Hungary), and nuclei of the met~.llurgical, metal-working and chemical industries. East Germany and Czechoslovakia were highly industrialized, but lacked a strong heavy industrial base, having concentrated on the manufacture of finished products. Although postwar industrialization has raised considerably per capita GNP's in Eastern Europe,~these remain considerably lower than those in most of Western Europe. In 1863, per capita GNP in Czechoslovakia and East Germany was less than three quarters of that in West Germany and about half way between the West German and Italian levels. Hungary_and Poland were in an_intermediate position, with per capita GNP's less than half a Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RD~9T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 of the West German level and falling between Italy and Greece. Bulgaria and Rumania were in the rear, at about the level of Greece. The combined GNP of these 6 Eastern European countries was about 10 percent smaller than that of West Germany and came to roughly one third of the combined GNP's of the EEC countries or the USSR. The 6 countries range in size from Poland - the largest - whose GNP is about half that of Italy, to Bulgaria - the smallest - whose GNP is about four fifths of Norway>> . Two alternative sets of figures for GNP and per capita GNP in Eastern and Western European countries are shown in table 1, and the methods of calculation are described in Appendix A. The GNP's of the Eastern European countries were estimated through direct comparisons with West Germany by means of calculated exchange rates and quantity indexes. The relatives so obtained were applied .to two estimates of the dollar value of GNP in West Germany -- one with the official exchange rate, the other with a calculated exchange rate obtained from a study for the OEEC. The results are shown in table 1. The ranking of the Eastern European countries as to industrial production per capita is similar to that for GNP per capita, although, as might be expected, the differences among countries are greater. Estimates of the relative levels of industrial production, total and per capita; are shown'in table 2. My estimates, which are described in Appendix A, apparently are nearly identical to those made by the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (CEMA). Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12 :CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 * See Appendix A for methodology. Approved For Release 2001/04/12 :CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Comparison~~ of Industrial Production, 1961 Total Eastern Europe 100_ My Estimates CEMA Estimate ~ Total Per Capita Total East Germany 28 165 28 Poland 26 90 27 Czechoslovakia 23 165 23 Rumania 11 80 12 Hungary 8 60 7 Bulgaria ~+ 50 3 Total Eastern Europe 100 100 100 West Germany 123 220 USSR 262 ~ See Appendix A ~ See Planowane Hospodarstvi noo 4, April 1, 1964 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 The differences among Eastern European countries and between them and are more pronounced for _ Western Europe ~ per capita GNP and industrial production than for the -sectoral distribution of GNP at factor cost, which is shown in table 3. The contribution of agriculture to GNP is considerably larger in most of the Eastern European countries than in nearly all the Western European countries -- which was to be expected -- and the contribution of services (all sectors other than industry., --__ -- ' ana - --construction, and agriculture; and forestry) is smaller. The contribution of industry to GNP on the average is only slightly smaller in Eastern Europe than in most of Western Europe, in spite of the fact that the relative volume of industrial output is much smaller. This may be due to high relative costs of industrial production iri Eastern Europe, particularly in such countries as Bulgaria and Poland, although differences in the method of calculating factor costs may also have strong. effects on the sector shares. II. Statistics and Methods Comparisons of economic growth and performance require comparable statistics and until recently, such. statistics did not exist for Eastern Europe. In recent years, however, a great deal of work. has been done to recalculate economic aggregates and indexes for Eastern Europe using Western-type methods. Much of this work has been a product or an outgrowth of the Project on National Income in East-Central Europe at Columbia University, under the direction of Thad Alton, who has published 3 monographs Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-R~P79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Table 3 Percentage Distribution of GNP at Factor Cost, 1960 Percent of GNP Originating in Industry ...and....... Construction Agriculture and. ~ Forestry Other. Sectors (Services) Bulgaria 39 29 32 Czechoslovakia 52 15 33 East Germany 54 9 37 Hungary 40 24 36 Poland 41 31 28 Austria 55 13 32 Belgium. 45 8 47 Denmark 42 18 40 France 49 10 41 West Germany 55 7 38 Greece 28 ~ 28 44 Italy 48 19 33 Netherlands ~ 44 12 44 Norway 39 11 50 For sources and methods, see Appendix Bo _ e Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 and a number of occasional papers (See appendices). The statistical analysis of this paper for Eastern Europe is based predominantly on these recalculated series. The official series (on national income, industrial production, and so forth) differ considerably in concept and method from the recalculated series and tend to show considerably higher rates of economic growth. Although very sound analysis of trands in the individual countries can be based on judicious use of official statistics (as for. example in the ECE's Economic Survey of Europe and Economic Bulletin for Europe), the same is not true of international comparisons. Moreover, the differences in methodology between Eastern and Western countries are such that rule-of-thumb adjustments (for example, to achieve greater comparability of coverage) rarely suffice -- complete recalculations are usually necessary: The differences in methodology can indeed be crucial to an evaluation of comparative economic performance. For example, the United Nations' Economic Commission for Europe in an otherwise very thorough and competent study drew what I believe are wholly incorrect conclusions as to the relative .productivity of investment in Eastern and Western Europe by relying on official series, with adjustments, for both sets of countries. According to the ECE, returns to investment during the 1950's were probably not greater economies in market than in planned economies. Zhe use of recalculated series for fact considerably greater in market than in planned economies. ~4pFoel~~e ,~OD~~/42 :$961~~F~~9~?~D49~QI32bb110~1e3Factors in ECO?70?!1C GrnvTt~'1 7 Tl FE~77'C~~P (j177'l Tlf2 "rY1P l Q~iCI t c . ~~=c~r~ri ~7l zr (`h ~rtoY? TT T. '~nl Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Official Eastern European measures of the growth of national income are not comparable to Western-type measures for 3 main reasons. First, the Marxist concept of national income excludes so-called "non-productive services" (that is, direct governmental and private services and often also passenger transportation). In postwar Europe the output of direct services generally has grown more slowly than the output of goods so that their exclusion has tended to raise the rate of growth of national income. Second, market prices -- the basis of valuation for national income in Eastern Europe -- differ drastically frorn factor costs in these countries. This is because of the absence of explicit charges for the use of capital Approved Ford Release 2001/04/12: CIA-F~1d79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 and land and the collection of the resulting savings in accounting costs by the government in the form of the turnover tax. The turnover tax is levied mainly on industry, whose weight in national income is thereby increased, at the expense mainly of that of agriculture. Since industry income usually is the most dynamic sector the rate of growth of nationa7.~is raised. Third, the method of calculating the growth of individual sectors of the national income differs from that used in the West. Although some of the Eastern European indexes of income originating in industry and other sectors give reasonable results, others do not, and little is known about them. Official indexes of gross industrial production in Eastern Europe in my opinion overstate considerably the rate of growth. The main reason is that industrial production indexes in Communist countries are not just measures of the results of industrial activity, but also are devices for the direction of industry and the establishment of producers' incentives. . Industrial managers, whose success often depended on fulfilling a plan 'for gross industrial production, had every incentive to produce an assortment of goods and to negotiate prices that would show the best results for the smallest effort. Altho h there were a multiplicity of controls designed to specify assortment and fix prices, these controls rarely prevented an inflation of the gross production index. ~ These points are developed further in Maurice Ernst, 'Overstatement of Industrial Growth in Poland", Quarterly Journal Of Economics, Noveiriaer 1965. Approved Fpr Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 III. Growth of Production A. Gross National Product Postwar economic growth has been rapid in both Eastern and Western E~rope~ (See table ~-~. In Western Europe total GNP in 1964 was about double the 1950 level and two and a half times the prewar level; in Eastern Europe, total GNP in 1964 was double both the 1950 and the prewar level. Economic recovery from the effects of World War II was more rapid in Western Europe than in Eastern Europe. By 1950, the Western economies were well beyond in the case prewar levels, except~_~_ .of Greece, where the effects of the civil war were felt for yeaxs. By contrast, GNP fell short of prewar levels in East Germany by 15 percent and in Hungary by 5 percent, just reached this level in Rumania, and showed a significant rise in Poland only because the change in boundaries greatly increased that countryes economic potential -- in postwar boundaries Polish GNP in 1950 was at least 10-15 percent lower than in 1937 ' After 1950, the Western European economies combined',grew somewhat ' faster than the Eastern European economies; combined, mainly because of the large weight and unusually rapid growth of West Germany. If we compare average growth rates with each country having equal weight, the rates in the East are about the same as those in the West. The growth rates in Eastern Europe vary inversely with per capita GNP, East Germany being an exception because of its delayed recovery -- after 1955, East German growth is the slowest in the area. Tn Western Europe, growth ~ that is, the Eastern E~zropean countries and the 9 Western European countries listed earlier. ' Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 12 _ Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RQP79T01049A003200110001-3 , s? Table 4 Growth of GNP, Prewar to 1964 Indexes 195 =10.0 Annual Percenta a Increases Prewar 1950 1955 19 0 19 1951-55 7-95 - 0 19 1- 1951- Bulgaria ~ 68 75 loo 142 168 5.9 7.3 4.3 5.9 Czechoslovakia 79 84 100 137 145 3.6 6.6 1.3 4.0 East Germany 84 71 100 127 141 7.2 4.g 2.7 5.1 Hungary 80 76 loo 123 ~ 147 5.5 4.2 4.6 4.8 Poland 72 79 100 127 155 4.8 5.0 5.0 4.9 Rumania - 66 66 100 119 144 8.6 3.5 4.9 5.7 Total Eastern Etizrope 76 76 100 128 48 5.7 5.2 3.6 4.9 Unweighted average 5.9 5.2 3.8 5.1 Austria 62 74 100 129 151 6.1 5.2 4.2 5.2 Belgium 67 84 l00 112 .133 3.6 2.3 ~ 4.3 3.3 Denmark ~ 68 91 100 127 157 2.0 4.9 5.5 4.0 Prance ~ 66` 80 100 126 155 4.4 4.8 5.3 4.8 West Germanys 51 65 100 135 163 9.1 6.2 4.8 6.8 Greece ~ 93 71 100 131 183 7.0 5.6 8.7 7.0 Italy 71 75 100 133 165 6.0 5.9. 5.5 5.8 Netherlands 58 76 100 122 146 5.6 4.1 4.5 4.7 Norway 62 84 100 117 143 3.6 3.2 5.1 3.9 Total Western E~irope 62 75 loo 129 157 5.9 5.2. 5.1 ?5.4 Unweighted average 5.3 ~ 4.7 5.2 5.0 ~ Calculated from unrounded data. ~-~ Excluding the sear. For sources and methods, see Appendix B Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001.-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 rates range widely, from around 7 percent (Greece and West Germany) to 3.3 percent (Belgium.), with, no clear pattern. There have been marked changes in growth rates over the years. On the average, growth in both Eastern and Western Europe was only a little slower in the second half than in the first half of the 1950ts. An acceleration of growth in Czechoslovakia and Bulgaria was more than offset by a deceleration in East Germany, where postwar recovery finally had ended, in Hungary, as a result of the 1956 revolt, and in Rumania, mainly because of poor results in agriculture. Since 1960, however, growth in Eastern Europe has slowed considerably, while there has been little change in the'Western rates. The sharp slowdown in Eastern Europe is due almost entirely to the severe economic recession in Czechoslovakia and a cut of nearly one half in the East German growth rate in comparison with 1956-60. Czechoslovakia sustained one of the highest growth rates in Europe during the late 1950is and in 1960. Growth slowed a little in 1961 and considerably in 1962. Then GNP fell nearly 3 percent in 1963 and did not rise in 196+; no other industrial country has had a more severe economic recession since World War II. The East German slowdown came at least a year earlier, under the strain of the Berlin crises and the sudden collectivization of agriculture, but it was not as severe as that in Czechoslovakia, annual growth having been fairly steady since 1962. Among the other Eastern countries, the sharp decline in Bulgarian growth reflects mainly the economic consolidaticn zollowing an extremely rapid expansion during the "great leap" of 1959-60 and the increased rate of growth in Rumania Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-R~79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 is influenced by the fact that 1960 was a bad agricultural year. Growth accelerated slightly in Hungary and decelerated slightly in Poland. Polish growth has been remarkably stable since 1950? In Western Europe growth rates increased during 1961-6~+ in 6 countries out of 9 and decreased substantially only in West Germany, which fell from first to sixth place among the 9 countries. Some of the ranking of growth rates, although not the broad relationships between the Eastern and Western countries, are changed if we compare the growth of per capita GNP's (table 5)o The largest difference is for Poland, where boundary changes, war losses and migration after the war caused a large decline in population. By 1950, Polish GNP per capita was about 50 percent above prewar levels ( in the old boundaries although total GNP had risen only 10 percent. In Czechoslovakia also, where the expulsion of the Sudeten Germans reduced the population, per capita GNP had .increased almost one third from 1937 to 195o with a 7 percent growth in total GNP. During the early postwar .years East Germany gained some population, although much less than West Germany, as a result of the expulsion of Germans from the areas acquired by Poland. Between 1950 and 1962, however, the East German population declined steadily because of its unfavorable age structure and the flight to West Germany, while the West German population grew rapidly. In consequence, the groS,rth of East German GNP per capita is about the same__as ~J'that of West Germany for the postwar period (it is much smaller in comparison with prewar in spite of a lag of one third in the growth of total GNP. On a per capita basis, Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Table 5 Growth of GNP and GNP per Capita Percentage Increases Prewar to i964 1950 to 1964 GNP __._ .. Population .GNP per Capita GNP Population GNP per Capita Bulgaria 148 21 105 123 12 99 Czechoslovakia 84 - 3 90 73 - 13 53 East Germany 6g 6 59 100 - 6 113 Hungary 83 10 66 93 8 78 Poland 116 -10 140 g6 25 56 Rumania 117 21 79 117 16 ~ 87 Total above 94 3 88 g4 13 72 Austria 146 6 132 103 4 95 Belgium 97 12 76. 58 g 45 Denmark 129 24 84 73 10 57 France 136 15 105 93 16 66 West Germany 219 39 129 151 17 114 Greece g7 20 64 157 12 129 Italy 132 17 g8 121 9 103 Netherlands 150 3g 80 g2 20 60 Norway 128 27 80 70 13 50 Total above 155 23 107 110 15 83 Sources for Population: U.So Bureau of Census and OECD Statistics. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 a Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 countries Hungarian growth is about average among -European ~ while Polish growth is one of the slowest. B. Pattern of Economic Growth Industrialization has been the dominant form of economic growth in Eastern Europe. As shown in table 6, industry and construction account for about 70 percent of the postwar increase in GNP in East Germany and Czechoslovakia and for nearly 60 percent even in so undeveloped a country as Bulgaria (twice as high a share as in Greece . The role of agriculture in total growth ranged from small (10 percent of so) to negative and the role of services ranged from a quarter to a third. The contribution of industry and construction to total economic growth was smaller in 6 out of g of the listed Western European countries than in any of the Eastern countries in spite of a generally higher initial level of industrialc~velopment, while the contribution of services was generally much larger. 1. Industrial Production Industrial production has increased more rapidly in Eastern Europe than in Western E~irope over the entire postwar period, and at about the same rate as in Western Europe since 1960, as shown in table 7. All of the Eastern countries, except East Germany, had easily surpassed prewar levels by 195o and since then annual rates of growth have averaged around 8 percent in Eastern Europe compared with 6 or 7 percent in Western Europe. As in the case of GNP, however, industrial growth in the Eastern countries has slowed ~ Industrial production is here defined to include construction and all handicraft production, Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Table 6 Composition of the Growth of GNP at Factor Cost 1951-1964 Percent of Increment in GNP Industry Agriculture Services (incl. Construction) (incl. Forestry) Bulgaria ~ 59 9 32 Czechoslovakia 68 - 2 34 East Germany ~ 72 0 28 Hungary 59 9 32 Poland 66 11 23 Austria 62 7 31 Belgium ~ 53 3 44 Denmark 48 8 44 Fiance 55 5 40 West Germany 63 3 34 Greece ~ 30 22 48 Italy ~ 65 11 24 Netherlands 51 3 ~+6 Norway 40 ~ - 1 61 aJ 1951-~3 1951-62 cf 1956-64 1~. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Table 7 Growth of Industrial Production, Prewar to 196+ Indexes .1955=100. Annual Percenta a Increases? Prewar 1950 1955 19 0 19 19515 195 - 0 19 1- 1 951- Bulgaria ~+0 67 l00 183 250 8.~ 12.7 8.2 9.9 Czechoslovakia 6g 80 100 155 167 ~+.6 g.l 1.9 5?~+ East Germany 80 59 100 l~+l 166 11.2 7.2 ~+.1 7.7 Hungary 57 65 loo 131 179 9.0 5.5 8.2 7.5 Poland 53 63 loo 1~+8 196 9.6 8.1 7.3 8 . ~+ Rumania ~+9 69 100 157 21+x+ 7.6 9 . ~+ 11.7 9 . ~- Tota1 above 61+ 67 100 11+8 185 8.5 8.1 5.8 7.6 Unweighted average 8.1+ 8.6 6.9 8.0 Austria ~ 1+7 ?~ 69 100 131+ 159 7.8 6.0 1+.3 6.2 Belgium 63 80 100 110 139 1+.5 1.8 6.1 ~-.0 Denmark 59 ~ 90 100 . 130 168 2.0 5.5 6.5 1+.5 France 65 79 100 J 131 166 1+.9 5.6 6.1 5.5 West Germany 51 56 100. 138 170 12.1 6.6 5.5 8.2 Greece 60 67 100 150 200 8.2 8.5 7.~- 8.1 Italy ~-8 60 loo 150 199 to . 6 8 . ~+ e 7.3 8.9 Netherlands 52 75 100 130 . 158 5.9 5.5 1+.9 5.5 Norway 50 82 100 111+ 11+1 ~-.1 2.7 5.5 1+.0 Total above 55 67 100 135 170 8.3 6.2 5.9 6.8 Unweighted average 6.7 5.6 5.8 6.1 Includes construction for post war years, except Rumania and East Germany. Excludes construction for prewar years. See Appendix B. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 down since 1960, largely because of the recession in Czechoslovakia,--- where industrial production in 1964 was below the 1962 level,-- and a fall of nearly one half in the rate of growth in East Germany. Rates of industrial growth in both Eastern and Western Europe have been inversely related to the level of economic development and there is little difference in rates of growth among countries at similar levels of economic development. For example, the 3 least developed countries, Bulgaria, Rumania and Greece have been at or near the top in industrial growth rates, with Greece lagging somewhat behind the other 2 because of its more balanced economic development; in the next group, Poland and Hungary have lagged slightly behind Italy; and in the more advanced group, growth in Czechoslovakia has been about the same as that in France and the Netherlands. Eastern and Western Germany have been exceptions, both being industrialized countries with high growth rates until recent years, and West Germany has had the edge. 2. Agricultural production In contrast to industrial production, which grew quickly in all the Eastern European countries, agricultural production in the area has barely surpassed the prewar level, while it is more than 50 percent above this level in Western Europe. A substantial lag in Eastern European agriculture in comparison with Western E~,irope developed in the early postwar years and the lag increased during the postwar period. Only in Poland, Rumania, and Bulgaria did production in the early 1960ts exceed the average for 193+-38, and most ~ Agricultural production refers to the contribution of agriculture, forestry and fishing to the GNP in constant prices. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RD~T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 of the Polish gain is due to boundary changes. The more developed countries did much worse. Production in East Germany was 20 percent, and in Czechoslovakia nearly 10 percent, below the prewar level, and in neither of these countries has there been an upward trend since the early 1950's. (see table 8). 3. Services This residual category of GNP is a composite of transportation, trade, and direct services, such as housing, personal services, and government services. Rates of growth vary a great deal among these components and, for individual components, among countries. By and large, the output of transportation, communications, and trade, approximately kept up with the during the postwar period. direct total output of goods In the case of~services, government services increased much faster than direct private services and housing in the Eastern European countries -- indeed, the output of many personal services declined. In the Western countries the differences are in the same direction but less marked, .These differences in both areas are offsetting, and production of services rose at about the same rate as GNP in almost all of the countries covered. (see table g). IV. Trends in Consumption and Consumer Welfare The Eastern European consumer has not benefited in proportion to the growth of production. In the Western European countries, the growth of personal consumption since World War II and since prewar years has almost kept up with the growth of GNP, In the Eastern European countries, for which reliable consumption statistics are available (they are not for Bulgaria and Rumania), the growth in personal consumption was much slower than that of GNP (table 10). Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 ~~ 1' ~ Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Z`rends in Agricultural Production Indexes: 1950-53 average=100 Prewar 1960-63 Average Bulgaria g6 ~ 107 Czechoslovakia 114 105 East Germany 122 g8 Hungary 120 118 Poland 95 .126 Rumania 112 144 Austria 106 129 Belgium 75 131 Denmark 77 117 France 89 134 West Germany 88 119 Italy 85 125 Netherlands 77 123 Norway 85 g6 Notes: Western Europe 1950-53 to 1960-63: GNP originating in .agriculture and forestry in constant prices. Prewar to 1950-53~ Agricultural output, excluding forestry (total agricultural production less the use of self-produced materials). See Appendix B. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Z`rends in the Output of Services 1951-196+ Annual Percentage Ratio of Rate of Increases Growth of Services _ _ to Rate of Growth of GNP_ .~ in-percent Bulgaria 5.9 ~ 98 Czechoslovakia ~.2 105 East Germany 3.8 ~ 69 Hungary ~- . ~- g2 Poland 3.9 ~ 80 Unweighted average ~+.~+ Austria ~+.8 g2 Belgium ~ 3.0 ~ 100 Denmark ~+ . ~+ 110 Fiance ~+. 7 98 West Germany 5.9 87 Greece ~ 5.5 ~ 81 Italy 4.6 79 Netherlands ~+.~+ ~ g8 Norway 5.0 bf 135 Unweighted average ~+.7 a All sectors of GNP except industry, construction, agriculture, and forestry. 1951-63 1 1951-62 1 1956-63 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-Rg~P79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Growth of Personal Consumption in Relation to that of GNP Ratios of Growth Rates (in percent) . 1951-55 1956-60 1961-64 1951-64 Prewar-196+ Czechoslovakia 31 55 136 55 1+3 East Germany 160 90 22 11~+ 79 Hungary 36 100 $9 71 52 Poland 85 84 76 84 76 Austria 100 100 112 10~+ 94 Denmark 75 76 102 85 81 France 111 83 11~+ 102 78 West Germany 88 105 106 97 100 Itas-y 75 76 133 91 loo Netherlands 62 98 1~2_ 9~ __ Norway 67 94 80 79 -- See Appendix B. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 The most extreme difference is in Czechoslovakia, where personal consumption grew about half as fast as GNP, the discrepancy being most marked during the early postwar years. In East Germany on the other hand, consumption grew much faster than GNP in the early 1950ts and almost as fast as GNP in the late 1950rs. The reason was the open border with West Germany, which forced the East German regime to keep living conditions as close to those ~.n West Germany as possible. The closing of the border in 1961 made this competition unnecessary at a time when the slowdown in overall economic growth made it more impractical. Consequently, there was almost no increase in East German consuumption between 1961 and 1964. The postwar pattern of growth of consumption in Hungary clearly shows some causes and effects of the 1956 revolt. During the early 1950's the growth of consumption was less than 40 percent of that of GNP; since 1955 consumption and GNP have grown at about the same rates. In Poland, the stability of the ratios in table 10 hides some considerable fluctuations in consumption policy within the periods shown -- consumption was sacrificed during 1951-53~ favored during the "new course" of 1954, the disorders of 1956 and the period of consolidation of Gomulka's power in 1957; and again given a low priority after 1957? The effects of Communist policies and priorities on comparative changes in per capita consumption are shown in table l1. The increases in per capita consumption are much smaller in Eastern Europe than in Western Europe whether we consider the period since prewar years, since the early postwar years, or since 1960. Unusual circumstances explain the two exceptions -- the changes in 25 e Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Table 11 Growth of Personal Consumption per Capita. Percentage Increases Prewar to 1964 1950 to '1964 1960 to 1964 Czechoslovakia 35 20 5 East Germany 43 134 3 Hungary 24 47 16 Poland 97 39 10 Austria 119 100 17 Denmark 58 43 19 France 76 67 _ 18 West Germany 127 110 16 Italy 100 88 29 Netherlands -- 52 20 Norway -- 36 14 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 boundaries and the decline in population explain the large improvement in Poland since prewar days; and the late recovery and open border until 1961 explain the rapid postwar increase in East Germany. The only substantial increase in recent years among the Eastern countries, although a_~___~moderate one by Western standards, was in Hungary, a fact that has been noted by many travellers. Lags of this sort in the growth of consumption inevitably had dramatic effects on relative consumption levels. Table 12 compares per capita consumption levels in East Germany, Czechoslovakia, Hungary and Poland with those in West Germany and Austria -- of all the countri es considered, those which have the closest historical, social, and cultural ties, and so far which comparisons are most relevant to the governments and populations involved. ,Before World War II East Germany was roughly at parity with West Germany, with Czechoslovakia not far behind. Since the war personal consumption in East Germany and Czechoslovakia have fallen to around 60 percent of the West German revel. These two countries. also lost a clear lead over Austria, which they now trail by a wide margin; and Hungary, which before the war probably was at about the Austrian level ~ ------ ~' ___ _____f was some ~+0 percent below the Austrian level in 196+ and not much above that of Poland. These contrasts have been evident to travellers for some time but until recently the necessary statistics were not available. ~? If prewar consumption were known for the same year -- for example, 193$ -- in all the countri es, consumption in both parts of Germany would be higher than in table 12 relative to that in Czechoslovakia and Hungary. 27 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Table 12 ......Comparative level s, of. Personal Consumption Per Capita Prewar 1950 1955 1960 1964 West Germany 100 100 100 100 100 Austria 81 82 79 78 79 Czechoslovakia 95 loo 71 ~ 63 57 East German~r 95 54 68 68 60 Hungary 87 69 52 49 48 Poland 45 60 48 42 40 -~ 193 for West Germany and East Germany; 1937 for Poland and Czechoslovakia 1938 for the other countries Methods: Appendix A. For Austria linked with West Germany in 1955 using official exchange rate. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved ~8~~e~l~~s~e?t00 e/04~~2 :~IAtRDP a9Td0~~49~00~e001 ~OOop an countries in the growth of personal consumption is certainly large enough to warrant some definite .'jud gments on?relative changes in consumer welfare in spite of probable inaccuracies in the calculations and the fact that many other things besides the average volume of personal consumption affect welfare. Among the influences on consumer welfare that the personal consumption statistics do not reflect, some probably favor Western Europe,r~thers Eastern Europe. For example, the range of choice among products and models has been considerably narrower in Eastern Europe than in Western Europe. Recurring shortages of many products and the consequent need to queue up for hours, possibly to go home empty-handed, also has been a negative feature of the Eastern European scene. On the positive side has been the large increase in the supply of free, or nearly free, social services, such as .educational and health services and recreation, which, in contrast to personal consumption, probably was at least as rapid in Eastern as in Western Europe (although to make certain of this would take additional research . Most difficult of all to evaluate are the changes in the distribution of income among various socio-economic groups. his is still largely an unexplored subject on which available information is very scarce. My general impressions. on Eastern Europe, based mainly on Polish data, are the following. Among the various socio-economic groups the peasants since prewar days have had the largest increase in per capita consumption.?~ The main reason has been a shortage of agricultural products, caused originally by the disruptions of World War II, and later 29 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 sustained by the inadequate growth of agricultural production. Zhe Communist governments tried at various times to depress the farmersT terms of trade, but were never successful for long because of the high demand for food. Semi- skilled and unskilled blue-collar workers also saw a considerable improvement in their standard of living, particularly those who formerly had been peasants. These groups of workers gained from what appears to have been a general reduction in wage-differentials due both to egalitarian socialist ideology and the easy overfulfillment of work norms. They also were the main beneficiaries of the low prices of necessities, such as bread, and the rationing of housing at nominal rent levels. On the other hand, the skilled blue collar workers often suffered from these changes and the white collar workers lost the favored economic and social status that they had had before the war. The prewar middle class, of course, fared worst of all, and the relative and absolute position of managerial and professional people generally declined, although with some exceptions. According to a Polish estimate', which places the overall increase in per capita consumption from 1937 (old boundaries) to 1960 at 100-115 percent, the increase in per capita consumption of farm families was more than double that of non-farm families -- 125-150 percent compared with 60 percent -- (the increase resulting from the shift of population from farm to city also is substantial). The increase in non-farm consumption was due only in part to a rise in real monthly wages (30 percent). Other factors were the near elimination of unemployment, an increase in the number of bread-winners per family and a Leszek Zienkowski, Dochod Narodowy Polski 1937-1960 (Warsaw, 1963, PP?199-201). Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 large increase in moonlighting. Considering that the work-week lengthened and that the above Polish estimates probably have some upward bias,(the Polish figure for the percentage increase in total consumption is 25-~+0 percent above the estimate used in the present study)it is quite likely that the choice of weights largely determines whether average real wages increased or declined. In any case, real wages, and probably also per capita consumption, of some social groups certainly are still lower than before World Was II, and in 1956 -- the time of the Poznan riot and the near-revolution in Warsaw -- most groups of older workers had ample reason to believe that they were worse off than before the war. Although the other Eastern European countries probably experienced less dramatic changes in income distribution than Poland, they also had much smaller increases in average per capita consumption. The net effect on the real incomes of the less privile()ged groups, consequently, was probably similar to that in Poland. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 V. The Cost of Economic Growth A low productivity of investment has been the major cause of the lag in the growth of consumption in Eastern Europe. Eastern European countries used a considerably larger proportion of their GNP for investment than Western European countries to achieve similar rates of growth in output. The productivity of investment was lower in Eastern Europe in spite of several favorable factors, including a more rapid increase in industrial employment, a distribution of investments that favored industry at the expense of'the more capital-intensive service sectors, and relatively smaller needs for the replacement of fixed assets. A strong case can be made, therefore, for attributing the low productivity of investments in the Eastern countries to the economic policies and institutions -.tYiat. have characterized communism of the Soviet type. A. Volume and Distribution of Investment In both Eastern and Western Europe thekey factor in postwar economic growth has been the large and rapidly rising level of investments. The share of gross fixed investment~in GNP at factor cost increased steadily in nearly all Eastern and Western European countries during the entire postwar period, as shown in table 13. Typically the Western European shares rose from 20 percent or less in the early 1950's to near 25 percent in the early 1960`s, while those in Eastern Europe (excluding East Germany) went from the low 20's to near 30 percent. In East Germany The method of derivation is described .in Appendix B. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RD1~9T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Table 13 Size and Distribution of Gross Fixed Investment As a Percent of GNP a/ As a. Percent of Total Investment b~ ? _ Total Investment Investment in Industry ~ Investment in Agriculture ~ Investment in Services Investment in Industry Investment in Agriculture Investment in Services Eastern Etiirope Bulgaria: 1950-54 23.7 10.6 4.1 ~ 9.0 45 17 38' 1955-59 27.7 12.1 7.6 8.0 ~+~+ 27 29 1960-63 41.5 19.3 11.2. ~ 11.0 47 27 26 Czechoslovakia: 1950-54 23.5 10.6 2.3 10.6 45 10 45 1955-59 27.3 11.4 4.3 11.6 42 16 42 1960-63 27.7 12.9 ~+. ~+ to . ~+ 46 l6 38 East Germanys 1950-54 14.5 5.8 1.8 6.9 40 12 48 1955-59 19.4 8.3 2.2 8.9 43 11 46 1960-63 23.6 11.x- 2.9 9.3 48 l3 39 Hungary: .1950-54 25.9 12.2 3.6 10.1 47 14 39 1955-59 24.2 ll.0 3.9. 9.3 46 16 38 1960-63 27.2 12.0 5.3 9.9 44 19 37 Poland: 1950-54 21.1 9.9 2.0 g.2 47 l0 43 1955-59 25.1 11.0 3.2 10.9 ~+~+ 13 43 1960-63 28.1 12.5 3.~+ 12.2 45 12 43 Western Europe Austria: 1950-54 20.1 7.2 2.5 10.4 36 12 52 1955-59 23.1 7.8 3.2 12.1 34 14 52 6 6 4 0- 3 19 2 .1 -- -- -- -- -- -- Belgium: 1955-59 17.1 5.5 0.8 10.8 32 5 63 1960-63 19.1 6.7 0.6 11.8 35 3 62 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RQP79T01049A003200110001-3 Table 13 (Continued) As a Percent of GNP a/ As a Percent of Total Investment bf Total Investment Investment in Industry ~ Investment in Agriculture ~ Investment in Services Investment in Industry Investment in Agriculture Investment in Services Western Europe Denmark: ~ ? 1950-54 17.2 3.1 ~ 2.6 11.5 18 ~ 15 67 1955-59 18.6 3.2 of 1.9 13.5 17 of 10 73 1960-63 22.5 4.6 ~ 2.2 15.7 21 .1 10 6g F 4 8 ranee: 1950-5 .1 1 -- -- -- ~ -- -- -- 1955-59 20.3 7:4 ~ ~f 1.6 ~ ~f 11.3 ~ ~f 36 ~~f 8 ~ ~ 56 ~~f 1960-63 21.7 8.5 1 1.3 ~ 11.9 ~ 39 ~ 6 55 ~ West Germany: 1950-54 21.1 7.9 1.3 ll.g 38 6 56 1955-59 24.3 g.2 0.9 14.2 38 ~+ 58 1960-63 26.4 10.3 1.5 14.6 39 6 55 Greece: 1950-54 15.g 4.3 1.6 lo.0 27 lo' 63 1955-59 19.2 3.5 2.0 13.7 19 l0 71 1960-63 28.g -- -- -- -- Italy: 1950-54 19.7 6.8 2.6 ~ 10.3 35 13 52 1955-59 22.4 6.7 2.7 13.0 30 12 58 lg6o-63 25.6 8.5 2.6 14.5 33 to 57 Netherlands: 1950-54 21.5 6.g 1.2 13.4 32 5 63 1955-59 24.4 7.5 l.0 15.9 31 4 65 1960-63 .24.7 7..9.. l.o . 15.8 32 4 64 a. Percent at estimated factor cost in constant prices. See Appendix B. Distribution at constant market prices. Includes construction. Includes forestry. Excludes construction and handicrafts. Calculated from the distribution in current prices. 1956-59. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 A~~~o~i~~if ~r~~~ ~~~~~i0~a2s~aC~ingDPo9s O,~p49on00~20A110th0e I g 95o's and the heavy reparations payments to the USSR until about 1957 (see section VI below), greatly limited investment, which was low even by Western European standards. Since the ending of reparations, and especially since the raising of the Berlin wall, investments have increased rapidly, becoming a respectable share of GNP. Much more striking are the differences in the distribution of investment. Investment in industry (including construction) and agriculture (including forestry) took a much larger share of total investment in Eastern Europe than in Western Europe; investment in services, a correspondingly much lower share. The Eastern European countries put a remarkably uniform 45 percent of investments into industry and construction, while few of the Western shares, even in the most industrialized countries, approached ~+0 percent and one (Greece) was as low as 20 percent, less than half that of Bulgaria. The share of agriculture in total investment is much greater in Eastern than in Western Europe not only in absolute terms but also in comparing countries where the relative importance of. agriculture in the economy is similar (for example, Bulgaria and Greece; East and West Germany; Czechoslovakia and France). Moreover, in the East the share the contribution of agriculture to of agriculture in investment has been rising while ~ ___ ,,GNP has been falling. In one Eastern European country, Poland, agricultural considering the large size of the agricultural sector; investments have not been high by Western standardsf but as will be seen later, the exception proves the rule -- Poland is the only Eastern country which has not collectivized agriculture. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-R~79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 As a result of the higher share both of total investment in GNP and of industry and agriculture in total investment, investment in these sectors took a much larger share of GNP in the East than in the West, as shown also in table 13. .~ The counterpart of the high investment in industry and agriculture in Eastern countries is the low investment in services, - transportation, trade, housing, and so forth. Typically, the share of services in total investment has been around ~+0 percent in the East, compared with 60 percent in the West, although with wide variation among individual Western countries. An adequate breakdown of investment in services is lacking, but it appears that the East invested relatively less than the West both in "tertia~)ry" sectors like transportation and trade and in social overhead like housing. B. Productivity of Investment The estimates of the growth of output and of gross fixed investment provide measures of the productivity of investment. In accordance with usual practice, the reciprocal of the productivity of investment -- the ratio of gross fixed investment to the incremente_,~ in output -- was used-. ~ For the economy as a whole, these were obtained as the ratios of the percentages of gross fixed investment in GNP at factor cost to the average annual percentage inorease in GNP. For the 3 main sectors of GNP (Industry and construction, agriculture and forestry, and services), the ratios are the average shares in GNP of the sector's investment to the rate of growth in the sector's output, the latter being weighted by the average share of the sector's contribution to GNP. For all periods, the increase in output is lagged one year behind gross fixed investment -- for example, average annual investment in 1950-54 is related to the average rate of growth in output during 1951-55. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 We will call .this ratio the investment cost ratio (or just investment costs) instead of the more usual, but cumbersome term, incremental capital- output ratio. The investment cost calculations, the results of which are summarized in table 14, reveal some important differences between the Eastern and Western European countries. Investment costs in Eastern Europe were higher than in Western Europe -- on the average by some 25 percent for the total economy, by ~+0 percent for industry, and by a great deal in agriculture. Only for services were the ratios similar in the 2 areas. Very few Western investment ratios exceed those in any of the Eastern countries and the differences between the most comparable countries of the 2 groups are very large. For example, the Bulgarian ratios exceed those in Greece by 75 percent for the total economy and by more than 100 percent for industry; Czechoslovak investment costs are two thirds more than those of France for the total economy and more than double the French in industry; Hungarian and Polish overall .ratios respectively are only 25 percent above those of Austria and Italy, but in industry the difference is 100 percent and two thirds. Investment costs in agriculture were . astronomical in Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, and East Germany (in the latter country, net agricultural output declined), and were higher in Hungary than in any of the listed countries of Western Europe. However, Poland with its predominantly private agriculture, had a low ratio, even by Western European standards. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Table 14 Comparative Investment Costs, 1951-6~+ Gross Fixed Investment per unit of Increase in Output a) GNP Industry Agriculture Services Bulgaria 5.1 3.8 33.6 ~+.7 Czechoslovakia 6.7 1+. ~- x+0.0 7.8 East Germany b) 6.1 3.5 c) 7.2 Hungary 5.3 4.0 g.6 6.1 Poland 5.0 3.4 3.6 9.5 ifnweighted average 5.6 3.8 7.1 Austria ~+.3 2.1 7.6 7.1 Belgziun b) 5 . g 1+.7 3.6 7.7 Denmark ~ 1+.9 l.g 5.5 8.0 France ~ 4.1 2.8 4.5 5.7 West Germany b) ~+.6 2.g 8.3 8.6 Greece 3.0 1.8 n.a. 5.5 Italy ? 3.g 2.0 5.3 7.8 Netherlands 5.0 3.2 ~+.4 6.5 Unweighted average ~+.5 2.7 5.6 7.1 a) Increase in output lagged one year behind gross fixed investment b) 1956-64 c) Decline in output Note: Norway is excluded because its investment statistics have a broader coverage than those of other countries (they include all kinds of repair expenditures). Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RD~7 9T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Investment costs have tended to be higher in Eastern Europe than in Western Europe during the entire postwar period, but the difference has been growing in recent years, as shown in table 15. The astronomical cost ratios for Czechoslovakia during 1961-64 reflect the near stagnation of output in the face of a high level of investment, and the ratio in East Germany has become the second highest among the listed European countries after having been the lowest during the early 1950 `s, when a considerable amount of unused productive capacity still remained because of the delayed recovery from the effects of the war. C. Factors in Investment Costs The wide differences in investment costs are the key to a comparative analysis of the determinants of economic growth in Eastern and Western Europe. The remainder of this section will deal with some.of the factors that may have caused these differences in investment costs -- the growth and distribution of labor inputs; the sectoral and branch distribution of investment; the options and policies'regarding replacement of fixed assets; and a number of pertinent institutional factors and policies in industry and agriculture. 1. Labor Inputs The overall rate and pattern of growth of employment was similar in the two parts of Europe, as shown in table 16:x. In both ~ Comparable employment statistics are more scarce than comparable production statistics. Those shown in table 16~cover the 1951-62 period for most countries, but shorter periods for a few countries. 38 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 . Approved For Release 2001/Q4/12 : CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Table 15 Changes in Investment Costs . Gross Fixed Investment per Unit of Increase in Output Total Econo Industr y 1951-55 195 - o ~-9 1- 1951-55 195 0 1 , - 9 1- Bulgaria C ~+?0 3.8 7.7 4.3 2.6 5 5 zechoslovakia 6.5 ~-.l 25.2 5.1 2.6 . 12 2 East Germany 2.0 ~-.0 8.7 1.1 2.3 . 5 p Hun ar g Y ~+?7 5.8 6.0 3.8 5?2 . 3 6 Poland ~+. ~+ 5.0 5.8 3.2 3.6 . 3.~+ Austria 3?3 ~?~ ? 1 8 2 ~+ Belgium -- 7 ~ ? ~ ~ _ ? 6.7 -- 2 8 Denmark 8.6 3.8 ~+ ? 1+ 3.8 l . ~+ . l 7 France ~+.1 ~ 1+.2 ~+?2 -- 2.7 . 2 8 West Germany 2.3 3.9 5.5 1.3 2.5 . 3 li Greece 2.3 3.~+ 3.3 2.2 1 5 , . Italy 3.3 3.8 ~ ~+. 6 1 ? 7 . 1.8 2 ~+ Netherlands 3.8 5.9 5.7 2.8 3.2 . 3.6 ~ .Increase in output lagged one year behind gross fixed investment? Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 . Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Table 16 Growth of Employment and Output per ,Ilnployee,1951 - 1962 Annual Percentage Increases Employment b~ _ Output per~Ilnployee c~ . Total. , .. . Labor Force ~ Industry Agriculture Total Industry Agriculture Bulgaria 0.5 5.2 - 1.3 5.6 ~+.7 2.0 Czechoslovakia 1.0 3.1 - 3.2 4.2 3.2 3.7 East Germany 0.0 - 0.1 - 3.0 5.5 8.~+ 2.8 Hungary 1.2 ~+.6 - 2.1 3.~+ 2.8 3.8 Poland 1.1 3.5 - 0.8 3.6 5.1 3.1 Rumania 1.0 3.6 - 0.2 4.7 5.2 3.9 Unweighted average 1.0 3.3 - 1.8 ~-.5 ~+?9 3.2 Belgium ~ 0.3 0.1+ - 3.5 2.8 3.1 6.2 Denmark 1.3 2.0 - 1.6 2.5 2.1 3.2 France ~ 0.2 1.1 ~ - 3.5 ~-.8 ~+.6 6.5 West Germany 1.?5 3.1 - 3.0 5.6 5.0 1+.8 Italy ~ 0.7 ~+.5 - 3.0 ~-.8 /+.1 5.3 Netherlands 1.1 1.3 - 1.8 3.~+ ~-.l 3.9 Unweighted average O..g 2.1 .. - 2.7 ~-.0 3.8 5.0 Industry includes construction except in East Germany and Rumania); agriculture includes forestry. 1951-62 unless otherwise specified. For Total and for Industry, 1951-62 unless otherwise specified; for agriculture, calculated from increases in output from the 1950-53 average to the 1960-63 average. Includes the unemployed and the military. of 1956-62. Sources: Eastern Europe, U.S. Bureau of Census; except for employment in construction. Employment in construction from various statistical yearbooks of individual countries. Western Europe: OECD Manpower Statistics, 1950-1962. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Eastern and Western Europe, the growth of the total labor force was less than one quarter as fast as the growth of output per person, and it is possible that there was no increase at all in the total number of hours worked in several countries. In industry both employment and output per worker increased faster in the Eastern than in the Western countries, but on the average the difference was greater for employment (two thirds) than for output per worker (one third). Agricultural employment declined in all the countries of both areas but on the average the decline was more rapid in the West, and consequently the advantage of the West was greater for output per worker in agriculture than for agricultural output. These averages disguise some wide differences among countries -- particularly the contrast between East German growth, which resulted entirely from increased labor productivity, and West German growth, which was supported by the fastest increase in employment among the countries listed. Nevertheless it appears that somewhat less substituting of capital for labor was necessary in most of the Eastern countries than in the Western countries to achieve a given rate of growth in output. A definite judgement on the relative role of labor inputs in Eastern and Western Europe must await a much more thorough study of the use of labor and also of education, training, and other influences on the quality of the labor force. But it is probable that the effect of labor inputs on relative investment costs was as worst neutral, and most probably tended to keep costs in the East lower than those in the West. ~+l Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 2. Sector~al and Branch Distribution of Investment The relatively high investment costs in Eastern Europe clearly are not due to the sectoral distribution of investments. Indeed, the opposite is true -- the sectoral distribution of investment in the 'keep East was intended to~ and should have. kept, overall investment costs lower than in the West. The reason is evident from table 14 -- investment costs are higher in services, into which the Eastern countries put a relatively small share of investments, than in the economy as a whole, and much higher than in industry (almost double in the Eastern countries and two and a half times in the Trlestern countries). The Eastern countries followed the strategy of maximizing exnenc3~_+tire_s~ ~:n the construction of new factories (or major expansion of old factories) by minimizing ____ _~ expenditures on the modernization of railroads, the construction of a modern road network, the expansion of warehouse space, and the satisfaction of consumer demand for housing. This strategy could be sustained for some years because to a point the use of capacity in these servicesr ~__ _~is quite elastic. It was hoped that the extra boost given to industrial production by concentrating investments in industry would be sufficient to allow the backlog of investment demands in services to be made up eventually without strain on the economy. These hopes were disappointed, however. We have seen that agriculture took a large part of investment with little yield (for reasons to be described later), and the expected advantage in industrial production did not Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 materialize because of the relatively low yield of industrial investments. Moreover, the possibilities for squeezing more output from existing capacity in _ sP,Rr~_c?s J__ ._ _; have been running out and in recent years industrial growth has been hindered with increasing frequency by a lack of freight cars (notably in Czechoslovakia , while great waste of agricultural products has resulted from the lack of storage facilities and adequate farm-to-market roads. In the future, the need to make up for the deficiencies caused by the short-sighted policies of the past probably will raise overall investment costs and hence limit the possible rate of economic growtho It is unlikely that these conclusions on the effect of the distribution of investment on investment costs would be greatly changed if more detailed comparative data on investment allocations were available. Within industry, the Eastern countries probably put a greater emphasis than the Western .countries on some capital-intensive branches, like steel and cement, and less emphasis on some labor-intensive branches, like textiles. On the other hand, chemicals and petroleum refining, which are both highly capital- intensive, probably were developed more intensively in the West. Replacement and Maintenance of Fixed Assets Eastern Europe had another advantage over Western Europe that should have tended to hold down its investment costs -- the fact that replacement needs took a smaller part of its gross investment. There are no comparable data on capital stock for Eastern and Western European Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 countries, but it is probable that Eastern countries, being in general less developed, had lower average capital-output ratios than-the Western countries both before World War II and in the early postwar years. It is also likely that the average age of capital was somewhat less in the East than in the West because the-.industrial revolution had started later. For both these reasons a smaller share of GNP is likely to have been needed in the East than in the West to cover replacement needs for capital. Moreover, since investment was a higher share of GNP in the East than in the West, the share of replacement needs in investment would have been smaller even if their share in GNP was the same. Thus it is probably safe to assume that net investment correctly measured -- that is, gross investment, less the expenditures required to maintain the productive capacity and efficiency of the existing capital stock -- was a considerably larger share of gross investment in Eastern Europe than in Western Europe. This means, of course, that investment costs in the East were relatively even higher measured with net investments than with gross investments. In practice, the Eastern European countries appear to~have tried to maximize the increase in productive capacity by minimizing retirements, relying on repairs to maintain the .productivity of existing assets. Again the intention was to hold down investment costs. The few available data on actual retirements of fixed assets indicate that retirement rates in Eastern countries, were extremely low. For example, they were less than one percent of productive fixed assets per year in Czechoslovakia during most of the Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 1950's.~ Actually, this policy probably had the opposite effect from that which was intended -- in the end, it probably increased investment costs. Expenditures on repairs, both capital repairs, which are included in the present investment statistics, and current repairs, which are not included, were high; but insufficient, leading to frequent breakdowns of equipment (the tractor standing idle for lack of spare parts is as common a scene in Eastern Europe as in the USSR), which in turn created unused capacity and caused a loss in efficiency. Moreover, the strong bias against retiring existing assets, long after they had become obsolete, caused some of the most productive investment opportunities to be unused. ~+. Other Factors Affecting Investment Costs We have seen that the growth of employment, the broad sectoral distribution of investment, and the maintenance and replacement needs for fixed assets all should have helped the Eastern European countries to keep investment costs below those in Western countries. The influence of external factors is discussed in the next section. Here we will consider from an internal point of view the effect of such factors as the introduction and use of nest technology, and the planning and management of production. In general, the relative backwardness of the Eastern European countries should have given them opportunities for a more rapid technological . * K. Novotny, "Vyoi=zakladnich fondu v letech 19+8-1957", Statisticky Obzor, noo 1, 1959, page 15 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Ac~~t~dr~~e~~r~0~1/Q~,~1~~1~9(T~'~~0@,,~~~,~0~~; often been . attributed to the USSR relative to the US). In addition, the relatively larger gross investments and probably much larger net investments in Eastern Europe; provided relatively greater means to take advantage of these opportunities. Among Western countries; high shares of investment in GNP usua]1y have been accompanied not only by a rapid growth of GNP but also by low investment costs. Large investment not only can mean a large injection of new technology, but also opportunities for introducing economies of scale in new and old plants. However, the relatively small size of the Eastern European economies tends to limit the possible economies of scale..__There could_be~offsetting opportunities in foreign trade, but these opportunities ,.''probably were less favorable in Eastern than in Western Europe. There is no way of measuring the actual development of technology in Eastern 'and; Western Europe. One gains the impression that new technology in Eastern Europe was inferior to that in Western Europe, partly for lack 'of effort, partly because of bad planning and management, and partly because of lack of access to the best Western and Soviet technology.,-.___ ___ J(technology in the Communist bloc was generally inferior to that in the West). Any technological disadvantage for Eastern Europe was bound to have the most serious effects on the industrialized countries, East Germany and Czechoslovakia. But techno~.ogical lags are by no means the only explanation for the high investment costs in Eastern countries. ~ See, for example, Angus Maddison, Economic Groi~rth in the West (New York, Twentieth Century Fund, 196+), page 77 and United Nations, Economic Com~r~ission for Europe, Economic Survey of Europe in 1961, part 2, Some Factors in Economic Growth in Europe durir_g the 1950's, Chapter II, page 20. . ~6 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Baal planning and management were. also important, and indeed, contributed .to the technological lags. An important source of inefficiency was the insistence on investing at. rates which strained the capacity of the construction and machinery industries. The result was unduly high costs and long periods of construction for new plants and an accumulation of unfinished projects well beyond what is probably usual in the Westo 'I~.e value of unfinished investments in Czechoslovakia, East Germany and. Hungary has amounted to about one year's gross fixed investment. In industry, the bulk of investments went for new plants, often in previously undeveloped sites, leaving insufficient investments for an efficient modernization of existing plants. (We have already discussed a similar bias in regard to replacement). =_ __ _ __ _________ The main recipients of investments in new plants were of course the least developed industrial branches and those where there was the least flexibility in the utilization of existing capacity. Most basic industrial branches =- at first, metallurgy, and later electric power, fuels, chemicals and construction materials -- had a great deal of new plant construction because they were initially relatively less developed than the branches producing finished goods and there was continuously an ~ See, for example, Andr2zj Karpinski, Zagadnienia socjalistyczr_ej _ industrializacji~ls'_~i ' (Warsaw, 1958), P~eS~9-92? ? ~' United Nations, Economic Commission for Europe, Economic Survey of Europe, 1962, Part 1, pages I - 20-23. 47 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 A~~~ ~~F~ors~el~~se 20A1I0~/1?t? GIAl-RD~79TQ11049A003200110001-3 r ge oz In usria ma eria s. Many new branches of the machinery industry also were built. Existing machinery plants and nearly all of light industry, however, received very little investment; their management was always under strong pressure to squeeze more output from existing equipment and what improvements there were entailed the installation of a few new machines, leaving production processes unchanged. Moreover, new plants in the East often were run at well below full capacity and produced at high unit cost for a long time after they had been commissioned. This was probably due partly to inexperience, at least in the less industrialized Eastern countries, but the principal cause was certainly poor planning of the plants and poor coordination of the construction of complementary facilities and of supplies and components. There are-also plenty of indications that bad management led both to unused capacity -- for example, the well-known "storing" of foundry capacity by machinery plants to protect themselves against possible shortages of parts -- and to unnecessarily high costs of production, which in turn held down the possibilities for increasing output. The institutional roots of such problems are well known; they will be taken up briefly in the concluding section. . nearly ?~ According to Karpinski, op. cit. pages 206-216 in _1955_ a_~-~_- the _m_ajor industrial plants built during 19+9-55 in Poland x~roc~.v.cec~. for .some time at higher unit costs than the old plants, in spite of considerably greater capitalization and an advantage in technology. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 The principal cause of the extremely high investment costs in agriculture already has been mentioned. The collectivization of agriculture, and before that the threat of collectivization and the discrimination against private farmers increased the demand for investment while they held down the growth of agricultural output. Collectivization increased the demand for investment in several ways: by creating a need for common livestock shelters and other "overhead" expenditures which do not necessarily raise production; by hastening the flight of labor from agriculture and hence the need for machinery to replace the labor; by tending to reduce the effective input of the remaining farm workers, at least those who work on collective land and livestock, and so again increasing the need for mechanization. At the same time collectivization tended to depress output ? because of reduced incentives for farmers to work hard, carefully, and skillftiilly _ -,~u Complaints are often heard from Eastern Europe that mechanization and other farm investments were inadequate. This inadequacy, however, is _ ;largely a reflection of the inefficiency of agricultural institutions.in using available capital. Inefficiency in the system of economic planning and management in Eastern Europe has been prevalent during the entire postwar period and was probably worse. during the early 1950's than today. Recently, however, it has been more apparent because it has become more of an obstacle to economic growth. Until around 1960, although plans for the cost of investment projects, the growth of labor productivity, and the reduction ~+9 Approved"For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 of unit costs of production were rarely fulfilled, production goals nevertheless were often achieved by mobilizing so-called "hidden reserves". There were many such reserves; mobilizing labor from the farm and the kitchen for use in industry; keeping obsolete equipment in production; making increased use of existing productive capacity in railroads, warehouses, and plants in low priority industries; and taking advantage of easy opportunities for the rationalization of production after industry had been nationalized. The government's ability to pass on the burden of inefficiency to the consumer, was another kind of "hidden reserve" for investment could be raised rapidly enough to generate high rates of growth Among the burdens passed to the consumer were the poor quality, assortment, and design of consumer goods. in output in spite of high investment costs. When increased consumer resistance and increased strain in the supply of raw materials were manifested during the mid 1950's, most of the governments had to temporarily lower or stabilize the share of investment in GNP, raise consumption and concentrate on straightening out the "disproportions" which had developed in the economy. New intensive investment drives were launched during the late 1950's, however, causing "reserves" once again to be used up at a rapid rate, and these drives were to continue during the early 1960's. Collectivization of agriculture, which accelerated between 1958 and 1961, made matters worse. By aboutE 1960 the reserves had nearly run out in the more industrialized colzntries, East Germany and Czechoslovakia. Agriculture had run short of labor, most housewives were already working, the strain on the railroad system had become excessive, and in many branches of the Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 A roved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 chinery and light industries equipment and processes were too obsolete to produce in accordance with modern technical specifications. At the same time, both domestic and foreign customers were becoming increasingly discriminating and large inventories of unsaleable goods accumulated, With the lack of production reserves and the greatly reduced possibilities for dumping low-quality products on domestic or foreign consumers, the inefficiency of the system of planning and management was bound to force a sharp slowdown in economic growth. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Ap~r~ved~FoLf2e~ease 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 VI. x ernal Fac ors The foregoing analysis indicates that economic performance in Eastern Europe was decidedly inferior to that in Western Europe. Production grew no more rapidly in the East than in the West; consumption increased much more slowly; and by all indications, economic growth was achieved less efficiently. It remains to be seen to what extent the Eastts inferiority in performance can be attributed to external disadvantages, for example, to Soviet impositions in contrast to U.S. aid, less favorable price terms, -br more limited access to foreign goods and technology. We will deal first with quantifiable aspects of external economic relations -- comparative trends in the volume~of imports; foreign aid and impositions; and the terms of trade -- and then evaluate the effects of these factors on economic performance and consider also non-quantifiable factors, such as the broad foreign economic environment. A, Statistical Evidence 1. Trends in the Volume of Imports Except in East Germany, trends in the volume of imports were at least as favorable to economic growth in Eastern Europe as in Western Europe. Imports grew very rapidly in both areas, as shown in table 17. Until the early 1960ts annual rates of growth in the volume of imports (that is, the value of imports in constant prices) were in excess of 10 percent in nearly all the Eastern European countries, and for the most part were below 10 percent in Western Europe. I?uring the early 1960ts, the growth of imports has slowed Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Table 17 Growth o= Imports in Constant Prices Indexes: 1955=100 Prewar ~ 1950 1955 1960 1964 Bulgaria 58 73 100 262 447 Czechoslovakia 58 64 100 189 258 East Germany 37~- ~ 37 ~ 100 194 233 Hungary 47 58 100 187 291 Rumania ~ ~ ~8 72 54 100 100 164 148 233 272 Total above 137 59 100 185 262 (excl. East Germany) 4g 65 100 Austria 60 61 100 167 233 Belgium ~ 66 75 100 141 207 Denmark n.a. 80 100 155 222 France 73 73 100 143 229 West Germany 78 ~. 47 100 146 214 Italy 46 64 100 199 297 Netherlands 59 72 100 146 211 Norway 65 71 loo 143 194 Total above n.a. 64 100- 152 224 East Germany and West Germany,-193 ; Poland and Czechoslovakia, 1937; Bulgaria, 1939; all other countries, 1938. Includes inter-regional trade between East Germany and West Germany. Includes Luxembourg. Sources: See Appendix C. All prewar data in prewar boundaries. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 in~apternd~oroRpeleaas~ a00e10era~edClA ~P~9r01~49op0320~e00ost31950 expansion began from levels which were already above those of the late 1930fs in all the countries covered, except East and West Germany. The exception for the two Germanies is due to the inclusion of estimates of interzonal trade in the prewar statistics. Interzonal trade had been far more important to East Germany than to West Germany, a factor which largely explains why the volume of imports in 1950 was only about 10 percent of that of 1936 in East Germany, while it was 60 percent in West Germany. In nearly all of Europe imports grew much more rapidly than GNP, as shown in table 18. Traditionally, dependence on imports had been greater in Western Europe than in Eastern Europe, largel~r because most of the Western countries were :mor.e industrialized. The prewar shares of imports in GNP had been surpassed by 1950 in all of Eastern Europe, except East Germany, but had not been in Western Europe, except in Italy and West Germany. Since 1950 the share of imports in GNP has risen steadily in every country and the difference between Western Europe and Eastern Europe has narrowed further. By 1964 the smaller Eastern Elzropean countries (Bulgaria and Hungary) had achieved higher import shares than the larger Western European countries and much higher shares than before World War II. The Bulgarian experience is especially noteworthy, the import share having increased from g to 24 percent in less than a decade. The Polish and Rumanian shares, however, continue to be much lower than those in Western Europe -- a reflection of the relatively rich resources of these countries in relation to their degree of industrialization. The contrast 54 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Table 18 Relation of Imports to Production ... " Imports. as. a. Percent. of. GNP . Import Index as a Percent of Industrial Production Index (from values in constant 1963 dollars) 1955=100 Prewar 1950 1955 19 0 19 ~ Prewar 1950 19 0 19 Bulgaria 8 9 9 17 24 146 109 143. 178 Czechoslovakia 6 6 8 12 15 84 80 122 155 East Germany 37~ 4 8 13 14 ~;?64~ 63 137 141. Hungary 5 6 8 13 17 82 90 143 163 Poland 3 6 6 8 10 72 114 111 119 Rumania 4 5 6 8 12 98 78 96 112 Austria 15 12 15 20 23 127 89 125 147 Belgium 25 23 25 32 40 106 94 129 149 Denmark~~ n.a. 19 21 26 30 n.a. 88 119 132 France 9 7 8 9 12 113 93 109 138 West Germany 18~- 8 ~ 12 12 15 153 83 106 125 Italy 5 7 8 12 15 96 l05 133 149 Netherlands 31 26 30 ~ 36 44 115 97? 112 133 Norway 25 20 24 29 33 130 87 125 137. ~ Includes inter-regional trade between East and West Germany. ~~ Includes Luxembourg in imports. Note: Prewar imports are in prewar boundaries while prewar GNP and industrial production are in postwar boundaries for Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia and Rumania. In comparable boundaries the prewar ratios of imports to GNP and industrial production should be somewhat higher than in the table in Bulgaria, slightly lower in Czechoslovakia, and considerably lower in Rumania. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 between East and West Germany remains striking -- the ratio of imports to GNP is only one quarter of the prewar ratio in East Germany while it has almost-recovered to the prewar level in West Germany. Imports grew not only in relation to GNP, but also in relation to industrial production in all the listed countries, except the 2 Germanies, as also shown in table 18. Industrial production recovered from the war faster than did imports in most countries of both areas, but then lagged behind imports during the post-1950 expansion. Surprisingly, imports in the Eastern Countries, except Poland, rose faster than industrial production even between 1950 and 1955; a period when all of the countries were trying to become more self- sufficient. Apparently, rapid and broad industrialization created a derived demand for imports so large that it swamped the effects of import substitution. ' 2. Foreign Aid and Impositions .Unquestionably the postwar balance on economic aid and impositions has been highly unfavorable to Eastern Europe and highly favorable to Western Europe. The Eastern European countries had to make large net payments to the USSR for reparations and other reasons and these net payments were concentrated in the early postwar years, when they were most burdensome. By contrast Western Europe was a large net recipient of U.S. aid and most of this aid was obtained early, when it was most needed. The following discussion of foreign aid and impositions and of international capital movements will treat these complex subjects only in very general terms, for a detailed treatment would require a number of specialized studies. 56 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Appproved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 No reliable estimate exists of Soviet takings from Eastern Europe, but an order of magniture of $15 to ~20 billion in postwar prices probably is reasonable to cover dismantlings, reparations, and occupation costs. The bulk ? of this amount (probably some ~10 to $15 billion) was taken from East Germany between World War II and the mid 1950 ~ s/_. __ __ a' ~(10 to 15 percent of East German GNP). .Another half billion dollars at least is accounted for by deliveries of coal by Poland to the USSR at nominal prices. Soviet removals of fixed assets and current production on reparations account from Hungary and Rumania also were substantial, although much smaller than those from East Germany. There were also Soviet takings from the jointly- owned but Soviet-controlled companies in Hungary, Rumania, and Bulgaria. The great bulk of all these Soviet impositions came between World War II and 1953, and the burden on the Eastern European economies probably declined steadily over this period. In comparison with Soviet impositions, Soviet economic aid to Eastern Europe (which was entirely in the form of credits, although repayment obligations for some of these were waived), was small -- in the order of ~+ billion, not much over one billion of which was extended before 1956. For its __ _~part, Eastern Europe extended some $2 billion in credit to non-communist developing countries, all after 1955, and about one billion dollars to other Communist countries. The large unrequited Eastern European exports to the USSR make a striking contrast with the even larger net receipt of U.S. aid by Western Europe. Total U.S. economic aid to the g Western European countries treated in this paper came to nearly $19 billion for 19+6-64 (excluding U'iQRRA aid), $16 billion Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 of which had been disbursed by the end of 1962. (the U.S. also extended a half a billion dollars of aid to Eastern Europe, consisting mainly of PL-480 credits to Poland after 1956). For the 1946-52 period, U.S. economic aid on the average amounted .to some 2 percent annually of the combined GNP's of the g Western European countries (about the average proportion for France, West Germany and Italy; a considerably large. proportion for Greece and Austria; and smaller proportions for the other countries). These figures exclude some $13 billion of U.S. military aid, which was disbursed mainly after 1952? They also exclude private long-term U.S. investments in Western Europe, which have exceeded the flow of official and private aid from the Western European countries to the developing countries. Both U.S. private investments in Western Europe and Western European aid to developing countries have become important only since the mid 1950's. To conclude, the balance of aid, impositions and credits was highly unfavorable to Eastern Europe for the postwar period as a whole, but the disadvantage for Eastern Europe (and the advantage for Western Europe) was concentrated in the early postwar years. Since the mid 1950's, both Eastern and Western Europe appear to have been net importers of long-term capital. 3. The Net Terms of Trade Rough estimates of trends in the "net terms of trade" (the ratio of the export price index to the import price index) are shown in table 19 for Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Poland, these 3 countries combined, and, by way of comparison, the EEC countries. The movement of the "net terms of trade" 58 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 is nearly the some for the 2 groups of countries, except that the changes were more favorable to the Eastern group between 1950 and 1955 and more favorable to the Western group between 1955 and 1960. But there were wide differences in trends among Eastern countries. Czechoslovakia suffered a marked worsening in its net terms of trade in the early 1950's, which it has riot yet made up, while Poland's terms of trade improved substantially from prewar years to 1950 and again from 1950 to 1955? These opposite trends between 1950 and 1955 may have been due to the stabilization of prices in intra-bloc trade at levels which favored primary producers, like Poland, but hurt importers of foods and industrial materials, like Czechoslovakia. In addition, there was a strong European market for coal, Poland's principal export of the early 1950's. The drastic fluctuations of Bulgaria's terms of trade appear to be due mainly to price fluctuations for tobacco, until recently Bulgaria's predominant export. There is no information on the terms of trade of the other Eastern Etiiropean countries -- the combined price indexes for Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia and Poland were used to calculate price and quantum indexes in Hungary and Rumania. But although the information is very spotty, it appears to indicate that trends in the terms of trade in the East were not greatly different from those in the West. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Table 19 Net Terms of Trade - Indexes: 1964=100 Prewar 1950 1955 1960 1964 Bulgaria 168 -- 111 99 loo Czechoslovakia 102 109 95 98 100 Poland 70 78 97 95 loo Above countries together 95 87 98 97 100 EEC Countries g6 87 89 96 100 ~ Ratio of export price index to import price index. See Appendix C. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 These findings on trends in the net terms of trade appear to be consistent with evidence on the pricing of Eastern European trade with the USSR and the West, which can be summarized as follows: (1) Soviet foreign trade statistics show that the USSR charges Eastern Europe higher prices and pays Eastern Europe lower prices than it charges and pays for the same commodities in its trade with Western Europe. 7~e evidence is convincing for Soviet exports, which consist mainly of materials and foods with fairly definite prices, but much less so for Soviet imports because most of these consist of manufactures, for which meaningful price data are lacking. ~ Horst Mendershausen, "Terms of Trade Between the Soviet Union and Smaller Communist Countries, 1955-19571`, Th.e Review of Economics and Statistics, No. 2, May 1959? "The .Terms of Soviet-Satellite 'T`rade: A Broadened Analysis , Ibid., May 1960. 61 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 (2) Eastern E~.iropean trade statistics show that the Eastern European countries obtain higher prices from the USSR (and each ,other) than from the West for their exports of the same commodities. Comparisons of import prices are inconclusive. Corroborating evidence comes from Western trade statistics, which seems to indicate that Western countries pay the Eastern opean countries less ~ j for the same goods than in their trade with other Western countries. It would appear, then, that (1) the USSR has better terms of trade with Eastern Europe than with the West; and (2) that Eastern European countries also have better terms of trade with the USSR (and each other) than with the West. - _ ____________ ___ ;- In other words, Eastern Europe appears to be discriminated against, on the one hand by the USSR, and on the other by Western Europe. There is nothing inherently inconsistent about this. A plausible explanation is that pricing in infra-bloc trade actually was based, as Soviet and Eastern European sources often state, on world market prices -- that is the actual prices used in world commodity markets or in contracts between large Western firms. The prices obtained in the West by the Eastern European countries were usually much less favorable to these countries than the ~ F`ranklyn Holzman, "Soviet Foreign Trade Pricing and the Qti.estion of Discrimination", Review of Economics and Statistics, May 1962. "More on Soviet Bloc Trade Discrimination", Soviet Studies, August 19 3. Frederic Pryor, The Communist Foreign Trade System (Cambridge, Mass., 1963), Chapter V. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 "world market prices". 'This is especially true of Eastern European manufactured goods, which suffer in world markets from tariff barriers, lack of publicity, reliable trade contacts and adequate- servicing facilities, and from inflexibility in the planning and management of foreign trade. ?Exports of raw materials and foods fare better, but even these tend to receive lower prices than average because they are often sold in small lots and at the wrong time. The basing of prices in infra-bloc trade on actual world market prices (with many modifications, including a tendency to stabilize the prices of raw materials for a number of years) would tend to create similar trends in the terms of trade as in Western Europe. This, as we have seen, is what the statistics appear to show. B. Evaluation What conclusions can be drawn from the statistical analysis as to the relative influence of external factors on the economic development of Eastern and Western Europe? It seems certain that Soviet impositions in the early postwar years and the unwillingness or inability of the Soviet Union to make up for the loss of inter-zonal trade had a great deal to do with the severe lag of the East German economy behind that of West Germany. ~.e enormous structural adjustments forced upon an economy whose imports in 195o were only about 10 percent of the prewar level can be imagined. East Germany had to develop a substantial steel industry, production of nearly all types of heavy machinery, and transportation equipment, and many other industrial branches. Some of this forced structural change was bound to involve a loss of efficiency in the allocation of resources -- certainly 63 0 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 initially, and probably also in the long-run. In addition the lack of imported materials for many years held down the utilization of exiting plant capacity and the growth of labor productivity. This massive readjustment had to take place simultaneously with an outflow of uncompensated exports to the USSR that cut deeply into investment possibilities. Economic recovery from the effects of the war had hardly begun in 1950 and during the early 1950ts, with the USSR taking 10-15 percent of GNP and with heavy pressure to improve living conditions rapidly, East Germany could not undertake a large investment program. As was shown. earlier, investments reached a respectable share of GNP in East Germany only in the late 1950's, after reparations had ceased. By contrast, West Germany adjusted very easily to its separation from East Germany because interzonal trade had been a much smaller part of West German than of East German trade, the West German economy was much larger and more balanced, and there were broader trade opportunities abroad and large receipts of U.S. aid. The evidence that measurable external factors were seriously disadvantageous is far less clear for the other Eastern European countries than for East Germanyo The quantitative growth of imports was certainly more than adequate to. sustain a rapid growth of output. Changes in the net terms of trade appear to have been generally similar in Eastern and Western Europe. In the early postwar years Hungary. and Rumania paid substantial reparations, and the other Eastern European countries, unlike the Western European countries, were not net recipients of aid, but since 1955 the Eastern Etiaropean disadvantage in this regard probably has been small. 0 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RD~9T01049A003200110001-3 Apo?VCpb~i~~c~cel~ ~~Qa.~~r4~,~~e ~aC~DP7procab~A0032oUn~0~a11y for the severe lag in East German growth until the mid 1950ts. It is reasonable to suppose also that they were largely responsible also for the lags of most other Eastern European countries behind Western Europe during the early postwar years of economic recovery and growtho Hungary and Rumania, the 2 after East Germany, countries which were probably most affected by Soviet impositions, were the latest to regain prewar levels? ___ _ J Except in East Germany, where Soviet impositions affected mainly investment, the main impact of these impositions (or the lack of aid) probably was on consumption. But these external factors do not explain the decline in rates of growth in recent years nor the high investment costs in all the Eastern European countries during the _, ___.postwar period. The preceding analysis, since it deals only with measurable external factors, leaves out a highly important difference between Eastern and Western Europe -- the general foreign economic environment. This difference, however, is both external and internal, and it is most appropriately treated as an aspect of the broad institutional and policy framework of the two areas. Membership iri the Soviet Bloc entailed among other things the adoption of Soviet-type economic policies and institutions and it is pointless to speculate about the extent to which Soviet pressure or the willing emulation of things Soviet by local communist parties were responsible. The application of Soviet-type policies and institutions in Eastern Europe had interrelated effects or. the domestic use of resources and on 65 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 f or~p o~tgdc~~i~Z`~}.Q~~Q4/1~~,~4?~~7-~Q11Q,OQ;'61(~'~3extent limited by Western controls, but Soviet and Eastern European policies were much more important limitations. For the individual Eastern European country, materials, foods, and machinery were almost always in short supply -- they could rarely be imported in the desired quantities and qualities. Consequently it was necessary to develop high-cost mineral resources, raise expenditures in agriculture to the point of small return, and overdiversify manufacturing production. Shortages of industrial materials were especially severe in the early and mid 1950's. In recent years availability of foodstuffs and technology have been increasing problems. Inability to import the most advanced or appropriate technology kept labor costs and often also investment costs higher than they might have This been : __~ a` disadvantage '_ _i'was especially burdensome for the more developed countries, East Germany and Czechoslovakia, which depended on advanced technology to maintain their lead in productivityo Moreover, the cost of doing without first rate technology has increased in recent years as East Germany and Czechoslovakia have exhausted the opportunities for tapping "reserves" of unused productive capacity and labor and as all of the Eastern European countries have faced more exacting customers abroad. Some of the overdiversification and development of high-cost production during the early 1950ts can be traced to a form of Soviet exploitation -- the levying of requirements on Eastern Europe for a wide variety of machines and other goods, without regard for prior experience, factor endowments, or 66 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 ecor~o~niese o fFos R~le ase~001/04 /gin CIA~a DP e9 hos04o9A00a200~~000a-3 --..most from such Soviet policies. Since the mid 1950's, however, the USSR has greatly increased its support for Eastern European economic development. The Soviet share of Eastern Europets total imports-has remained at about ~+0 percent since 1950, but since 1955 the USSR has supplied a growing share of Eastern European imports of industrial materials, some of which it produced at high marginal cost, and provided considerable amounts of grain in spite of domestic shortages. Moreover, the USSR has tried, althougk~ with little success, to bring about a more rational allocation of resources in Eastern Europe through intra-Bloc coordination of economic plans and specialization in production, thereby reversing previous policies. At least since the mid 1950ts, the external difficulties of the Eastern European countries appear to be largely symptoms of ailments which have affected all Communist countries. Shortages of materials were caused by excessively rapid increases in production of finished goods, by lack of coordination of national investment programs, and by inefficiency in the use of materials. Shortages of foods were due mainly to collectivization and to other policies depressing farmers' incentives. Lagging technology was the result of a system of economic incentives which rewarded increased production at any cost and penalized innovation and careful consideration of customerst interests. Uncertainty in deliveries of imported goods and components and the lack of flexibility in adapting import schedules to changing domestic needs reflected the general rigidity of management in foreign trade as well as the domestic economy. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 ~~~rov~$~~~~ ~fig~~P4~~~p?QT~.~d~9~i .1 ` 110001-3 One after the other, the Eastern European regimes have become aware of the poor performance of their economies, and have been groping for more effective economic policies and more efficient forms of planning and management. The revolution in Hungary and the`near revolt in Poland in 1956 brought home the necessity for change to the regimes of these countries earlier than to those of the other Eastern European countries. Although the consumer-oriented priorities adopted at that time in both countries and the partial decentralization of management in Poland were short-lived, economic policies have been much more moderate and flexible since 1956 than before, and this early adjustment to realities is one of the reasons why the rate of growth of the Polish and Hungarian economies has not declined. The Czechoslovak and East German regime, however, in spite of rapidly declining economic "reserves", tried to maintain or accelerate economic growth, relying heavily on Communist Party activists to create the necessary stimulus, and in 1959-60 the Bulgarian regime went so far as to try a "great leap" somewhat on the Chinese model. It was the sharp slowdown of economic growth in East Germany in 1961, in Czechoslovakia in 1962, and in Bulgaria in the aftermath of the "great leap" of 1959-60, that brought home the need for economic reform in these countries, and, this example has created new pressure for reform in Poland and Hungary. Only Rumania, which has achieved increased rates of industrial growth since 1958, has been generally satisfied with the old system of economic planning and management. 68 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Improvements in economic performance have been sought both through internal economic reform and through external assistance and international economic cooperation. The remainder of this paper will deal with the main outlines of these internal and external measures. A. Economic Reform Little by little, Eastern European economists and government officials have tome to recognize two basic deficiencies in-what we have been.callirig'the "Soviet-type economic system". Planning was not based sufficiently on rational economic considerations; management was not flexible enough to adapt to changing needs. Lack of rationality in economic plans was due sometimes to inexperience, but mainly to the primacy and overdiversification of political objectives. The province of economic analysis was Limited not only by politically-inspired institutional changes, such as the collectivization of agriculture, but also by the requirements imposed by politically-determined growth objectives. Until the past few years, moreover, economic analysis had to be performed with a very limited set of tools (such as the "material balances"~, the use of more efficient and appropriate tools, such as linear programming, having been barred for ideological reasons. The basic form of ownership and restrictive management aside, the most`, ` _ feature of the system for economic planners was the politically-determined rate of industrial growth. If, as was usually the case, this rate was set beyond the economics capabilities, extreme tautness in economic plans was inevitable and this entailed a forced "balancing" of the plans by such means as unrealistic Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RD~~9T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A0032D0110001-3 adjustments of coefficients for the use of materials, unrealistic estimates o investment costs, and.the-taking of resources from _-1ow-priority such as housing. sectors Moreover, the severe constraints caused by taut planning were felt by all levels of management which were forced to raise production by any means and could ill afford to risk cost reductions, product changes, or technological improvements that might reduce, even temporarily, the rate taut _ _ _ __ of growth of output. The same conditions created `__a _ ~ ~ . _='sellers' market for almost all goods and gave all but the highest priority customers little chance to b~ heard; instead unsuitable goods were accepted, processed, and passed on, until they finally were bought by private consumers, who or or had few alternatives, used at high cost in investment projects,exported to relatively undemanding foreign countries,,. - ~______~ or simply left in inventories. Taut, overoptimistic planning for the overall rate of industrial growth also had serious implications for the structure of investment and the pattern of economic development. Unable to obtain enough raw materials from the other Communist countries, which ,_ _ ;also had taut plans, each country had to invest heavily in slow-maturing projects in basic industries. _ ~ __ ~. If we add to this the politically-determined priorities among economic branches, lack of access to first ra-~e technology, and plain incompetence on the part planners, a good bit of inefficiency can be easily Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approve ~SyS~ema opf' 200ono4/i ~ manageDPrit9T~0SO49A00 X2 b0 e1 b00 a se it was a operated as~ huge bureaucracy, where each echelon made economic decisions on but with the basis of directives from above ~ insuffi~nt knowledge of the situation below. Constrained by what were often unrealistic a_nd mutually inconsistent directives, the ministries, and their subordinate units had to a work out all the details of~ production and distribution program`leaving the er~treprises little choice on how to put this program into effect. What choice there was consisted mainly in ignoring lower-priority goals in favor of higher-priority goals, and managers' efforts tended to be directed to pleasing the government (or Party boss rather than the customer. Moreover, a system of premia and other incentives which rewarded mainly fulfillment of gross production goals and an artificial price system which reflected neither marginal social costs nor consumer preferences created a poor basis for guiding unplanned decisions in line with national interests. The reforms introduced in Eastern Europe during the past two or three years are aimed at these deficiencies, ~~either Eastern Europeans, nor indeed Westerners, can ___ ,be certain how deeply the reforms will have to cut into the Soviet-type "command economy" to bring a marked improvement in economic performance. The best publicized, and possibly the most thorough reforms are being introduced in Czechoslovakia, ~ere.the number of obligatory production and input goals for enterprises has been greatly reduced, ifarious measures of profits are to be _a_ basis for bonuses and premiums. Part of investment decisions and most contracts with customers `~- Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 ~3'~i-o~c~Fo1~~d~~~~00~/04Yi'~2 e~l~T~h4~~~0U1100~~~gucer prices are to contain charges for the use of fixed capital (as is already being done in Hungary) and are to be influenced by market conditions at home and abroad. Similar changes are being introduced in East Germany and Bulgaria, and some at least are likely to be introduced in Poland and Hungary. In all the Eastern European countries there is great emphasis on "scientific planning", which involves not just balancing of needs and requirements but "optimization" of programs, based on centrally or locally determined criteria, with the help of electronic computers. The desire to develop the branches of production for which the economy will be best suited in the long-term, to use modern technology, and to compete on world markets has at least partly replaced the early drive to increase the quantity of production at all cost. While trying to make plans more rational and management more flexible, however, the regimes have tried to avoid any real loss of control over the economy. ~e meeting place of the new system of planning and management with the power structure of the state and Party appears to be at the newly-formed intermediate administrative units, called Associations or Trusts, which control either an entire industrial branch (for example, machine tools), or a vertically integrated set of enterprises. In East Germany and Czechoslovakia at least the directors of these Associations on paper have very wide powers, similar in some respects to those of Western corporation managers. They could in theory run their subordinate enterprises largely according to market criteria, or they 72 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 A~~e~~'F~F~a~/~4~-'F~ ?~Q~~--I~I~~D-'f~4~l~A~~(~A~~000 much pressure will be put on these raa.nagers by the political authorities and how the managers will react to pressure remains to be seen. B. International Cooperation and Foreign Assistance 1. antra-Bloc Economic Cooperation The search for increased efficiency through internal economic reform had a counterpart in the effort to promote economic cooperation among the Eastern European countries, but nationalism and the nature of the Soviet-type economic system have greatly hindered progress. The drive for increased cooperation, which began in earnest during the late 1950`s, was intended to invigorate a largely inactive organization, the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance, usually called CEMA or COMECON. It was hoped to achieve a more rational distribution of capacity in basic industries and savings in investments and materials through coordination of investment plans; greater economies of scale and better concentration of technological effort through specialization in the production of manufactures; and a more effective use of scarce hard currency through cooperation in trade with non-communist countries. In spite of high level political pressure and and innumerable meetings proposals, however, there was very little progress ~- trade in intra-bloc economic cooperation. Intra-Bloc continued to increase rapidly, but largely in the framework of bilateral agreements and as a consequence of separately established national plans. Specialization agreements have been limited to a tiny percentage of industrial output, 73 e Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 and apart from the construction of the'~'riendship`oil pipeline, cooperation . in investments has been minimal. ~e reasons for this failure are rooted in the very nature of the "command economy".~' packing any sort of automatic regulator and arbiter for economic decisions and conflicts, such an economy needs an ultimate authority to make or enforce any decision. But there has been no such authority internationally, and so no"way to force agreement on specialization, prices, investments, and so forth, or to apply sanctions in cases where agreements are not fulfilled. KY~ushchev's proposal in 1862 for the creation of a CEMA planning staff with some supranational authority no doubt was intended as at least a first step toward a Bloc-wide "command economy", but the proposal failed to be adopted because of nationalistic opposition, _notably_from_Rumania. - ~___,~ Failing a supranational authority, all of the internal weaknesses of the Soviet-type system of planning and management are magnified internationally, and its principal virtue, the ability to mobilize resources quickly for high-priority purposes, is inoperative. 2. Soviet-East European Economic Relations The most obvious source of assistance for the Eastern European countries to improve their economic performance has, been the USSR, the more so because of the lack of significant progress in intra-East European economic cooperation. As we have seen, the USSR has tried to help -- by providing some credits (since 1960, only to East Germany and See, for example, NLichael Kaser, COMECON - Integration Problems of the Planned Economies (Oxford University Press, 19 5 7~+ Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 A~~a~,for}~~~se~1~~~'I~yC~~~~~S719i,1g0'~0 o9A(~030~,0'111Q00~ 3, a1 materials. In 1863, the USSR covered nearly 100 percent of the area's net imports of materials and fuels, compared with two thirds in 1860 and only ~-0 percent in 1955, thereby enabling the Eastern European countries to use a large share of their scarce earnings of Western currencies to buy specialized machinery. increasing its It is unlikely, however, that the USSR will be willing to continue~support_-of Eastern European economic growth to this extent. Although the USSR gains some price advantage in its trade with Eastern Europe (as was indicated earlier , it is questionable whether this compensates for the disadvantages in the composition of trade. Soviet exports consist mainly of industrial materials and foods. Some of these, coal; for example, are produced at are produced high average cost, and many, including coal,-iron ore, and grain;~at rapidly rising marginal cost. The exchange of such goods for machinery and equipment, the largest part of Soviet imports,. is certainly profitable when the machinery and equipment embodies advanced technology that the USSR can produce only with 'difficulty__if at all. Such is the case for Soviet trade with the West. But this exchange may not be profitable when the imports consist of ordinary machinery and equipment, which embody the same general level of technology as is available from Soviet production. Most Soviet machinery imports from Eastern Europe probably are of this type. By all indications, both the average and marginal costs of most machinery -and equipment production in the USSR are considerably below those for raw materials and foods, and the gap is probably increasing.- Probably the 75 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Ap roved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 rfi~in advantage to the USSR in importing machinery from Eastern Europe rather than producing it at home. is as a source of flexibility. ~e Soviets have been able to import machines on special-order or in small batches, so that they could better concentrate on series production. In .recent years, the Soviets have added their influence to other pressures for raising the quality and technological level of Eastern European manufactures, and have increased rapidly their imports of consumer manufactures from that area. To the extent that quality and technology are improved, however, opportunities for Eastern European trade with the West are increased as well. 3. Economic Relations with the West Growing economic difficulties and the inability to solve .these difficulties within the Soviet Bloc have increased the demand in Eastern Europe for Western goods, capital, technology, and knowhow, and increased the receptiveness to Western ideas. The binds of Marxist economic dogma have been loosening since at least 1955?_ __'L'he thaw went quite far in Poland as early as 1956, but only recently has ___ _~ "market socialism" !become ideologically respectable in Eastern Europe. This intellectual revolution obviously has had a great impact on the economic reforms that are being undertaken.~~----``"~____~_ ,however, The trend has__beer~ less clear~in the more tangible aspects of economic relations. Western goods and technology have long been in high demand, but, except in Rumania, there was until recently little inclination to Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-R~~79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 treat trade with the West as more than a supplementary source of goods and .technology. The basic obstacle to increased trade with the West has been the inability of the Eastern European countries to market their exports of manufactured goods in the West, and their unwillingness to make the adjustments required for an expansion of such exports in the long-run. The temporary increase in the share of the West in Poland's foreign trade from 36 percent in 1955 to ~+2 percent in 1958 was due to U.S. credits under P.L. x+80 and a temporary shift in Polish exports of coal from Eastern Europe to Western Europe. With the ending of U.So credits and the weakening of the Western European coal market, the share of the Trlest in Poland`s trade has returned to about what it was before Gomulka`s accession to power. Difficulties in exporting to the West have caused the share of the West in total trade to decline also in East Germany, Czechoslovakia, and Hungary since the late 1950's. In the early 1960's the West's share. in these countries and in Bulgaria has been between 25 to 30 percent. Rumanian trade followed the opposite pattern -- the share of the West increased from 20 percent in 1958_to 32 percent since 1861. This shift was undertaken as an aspect of Rumania`s policy of enhancing national independence and accelerating industrial development. What made it possible was that Rumania's 3 major types of exports, corn, petroleum products, and wood were readily saleable in the West and that in addition Western firms were willing to extend large export credits to Rumania. 77 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 In the past two or three years there have been signs that the more industrialized Eastern European countries were beginning to lay a sounder basis for the expansion of their trade with the West. In 1864, for the first time since the mid 1950's, there was a fairly general rise in the share of Eastern European trade taking place with the West. Although it is much too early to see a trend from these statistics, there are other favorable signs. One is the increased flexibility in production which should result from the internal economic reforms. Because production, and hence the use of productive capacity, will no longer be planned in so much ,detail, it will be~easier for producers to adapt output mix to changing foreign demand. Although this increased flexibility will facilitate all foreign trade, it is especially important in the case of trade with the West. A second favorable development is the increased willingness of the Eastern European regimes to undertake production of manufacturing lines specifically for the Western market. East Germany is making a real effort to develop clothing production for sale in Western Europe. Joint production and marketing arrangements between Eastern and Western European firms (for example, the arrangements between Poland and the German firms Krupp and Grundig for the joint manufacture and sale of tape recorders) have been multiplying in the-past 2 years,may considerably enhance the and ability of the Eastern European countries to sell manufactures in Western Europe. These arrangements, like many Eastern European purchases of Western European equipment, sometimes include credit terms and technical help. But the original features of some of them are to provide Western technical and quality control over Eastern European production and in addition the 78 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 name and connections of the Western firm to sell in Western countries. This knowhow and "goodwill" may be as important as the basic production technology and their possession may save the Eastern European countries a great deal of time and effort. At the same time, the Eastern European countries have been seeking better terms for their exports to the West by negotiating with GATT, looking for Most Favored Nation treatment in the U.S., trying to make better arrangements with the EEC and its member countries, and so forth. Lower tariffs and higher quotas in the West would help Eastern Europe's exports. In the long-term, however, the prospects for trade with the West depend mainly on the Eastern European countries themselves -- on the way they allocate their resources, and especially on how much they are willing to change the economic system to which so many of their economic problems can be attributed. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 ? Appendix A Approved For Rel~~g'1~8?~l'I12 ~~~I~QSPd~T(b'I~O~~g~(~0~~~(~(~~-3 In all cases estimates of comparative economic levels (for GNP, industrial production, personal consumption) were made for a single postwar year. Comparative levels for other years were obtained by moving the base year comparisons by means of indexes for the individual countries. Western European Countries GNP in the Western European countries was obtained in terms of a common denominator (U.S. dollars in 1963 prices) in two alternative ways: (1) by applying official exchange rates to the values of UNP in domestic currencies in 1963 and (2) by using the geometric means of the two sets of dollar values in purchasing power equivalents for 1955 as estimated for the OEEC (Milton Gilbert and Associates, Comparative National Products and Price Levels, Paxis, OEEC, 1958), and converting these to`1963 prices by means of the U.S. official GNP deflator. For Austria and Greece, the only countries discussed for which Gilbert did not estimate purchasing power rates, it was assumed that the dollar value of GNP at purchasing power rates exceeded that at the official rate in 1963 by the same percentage as in West Germany and Italy respectively. The relative magnitudes of industrial production in Western Europe were obtained from the weights used by the OECD to calculate the combined industrial index for the member countries. Eastern European Countries The dollar value of GNP and personal consumption in Eastern Europe and the comparison of industrial production in these countries with Western Europe were obtained via direct comparisons between Eastern European countries and 80 ? Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 West Germany. The estimates for the Eastern European countries relative to West Germany were then linked into the comparisons between West Germany and other western countries. Consequently, two alternative sets of dollar figures for GNP were obtained for Eastern Europe, corresponding to the two alternative dollar estimates for West Germany. The year for the comparison with West Germany is 1955? West German data for that year exclude the Saar. In the comparison with West Germany, two sets of estimates were made which, in some cases, complement each other, and, in other cases, serve as checks against each other. _ (1) GNP at current domestic prices in Czechoslovakia, Hungary, and Poland (from sources listed later) ____`_ _'was converted to Deutschmarks by means of estimated purchasing power ratios for individual components of GNP. This calculation yielded estimates for the major end uses of GNP, as well as for total GNP. The calculations for personal consumption are more reliable than those for the other end uses. The Deutschmark values so obtained were then related to the actual values for West Germany in 1955? (2) Quantity indexes were calculated relating personal consumption, net industrial production, and net agricultural production in each Eastern European country to those in West Germany. The indexes were calculated from commodity samples in physical units, weighted by West German prices (except for the metal-working component of industrial production which was obtained by converting domestic values of production into Deutschmarks at calculated exchange rates). Group indexes for industry and consumption were aggregated by 81 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 means of West German .value weights (~,raiue of purchases for personal consumption; value added for industrial production). .For agricultural production, estimates of purchased inputs were deducted from estimates of agricultural output (net of own production used for feed or seed, or wasted). This set of calculations yielded values of personal consumption, industrial production, and agricultural production as relatives of West Germany,_~ _. ___ _ _ the first involving conversion by means of price indexes with Eastern European quantity weights, and the second involving quantity indexes with West German price weights. Both sets of calculations give results for Eastern EUSOpe`n West German Marks. Because of the tendency for relative quantities to be inversely correlated with relative prices, conversion of West German magnitudes into Eastern European currencies (the reverse of the above) probably would give less favorable results for Eastern Elzrope. Consequently, the original estimates for Eastern Europe were lowered by various percentages by analogy with estimates for other countries and on the basis of other information. mere were discrepancies for other reasons also, - }between the results of the comparison by means of price indexes and those of the comparison by means of quantum indexes. In the case of personal consumption, the price indexes were obtained using commodity samples which, although often rather. small, at least could be defined quite specifically in regard to type and quality of product. The quantity comparisonsJhowever, necessarily used broad, undifferentiated series, such as cotton fabrics in meters or tons, to represent 82 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 a very wide variety of products. The final estimates of personal consumption were based mainly on the price conversion for Czechoslovakia, Poland, and Hungary, The final estimate for GNP was a compromise between the results of the price conversions and those of a weighted average of the quantum comparisons for industrial production and agricultural production. 83 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Appendix B Measurement of Economic Growth Western European Countries All of the postwar calculations of the growth of GNP and its components by origin and use-are taken from OECD statistics. Series in constant 195+ prices were used for 1950-60. These series were linked in the year 1960 with the new series in constant 1958 prices. The linking was done independently for GNP, for industrial production (including construction) and for agricultural production (including forestry). The growth of services in constant prices was calculated as a residual-- a method which may give different results for the years after 1960 than the direct calculation of trends in services because the change from 195+ to 1958 weights had some effect on the measurement of growth of GNP. The alternative, which would have been to recalculate the growth of GNP in 195+ prices after 1860, was rejected. A similar method was used to calculate the distribution of and trends in gross fixed investment. The prewar estimates for Western European countries are mainly from OECD and FAO sources. Indexes of industrial production excluding construction were used to link prewar years with the postwar series of GNP originating in industry and construction, beginning in 1950. The agricultural indexes for prewar years are for agricultural output (net of feed, seed and waste from own production but not of inputs from outside agriculture) and exclude forestry. They were linked in 1850-53 (average) with postwar series for Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-R[~79T01049A003200110001-3 -oved For F~elease 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 originating in agriculture and forestry. ~e share of gross fixed investment in GNP at factor cost in the Western European countries was estimated by means of a rough rule of thumb. It was assumed that the correct relation would fall between two sets of estimates: (1) the ratios of gross fixed investment at market prices to GNP at market prices (which implies a burden of indirect taxes -- net of r__. __ , subsidies --_ __ proportionately as large on investment as on the GNP as a whole); (2) the ratios, of gross fixed investment at market prices to GNP at factor cost (which implies that there is no burden of indirect taxes on investment). The rule of thumb used in this estimate was to take the mid- point of the range of ratios obtained with methods (1) and (2). For some countries this method may give rise to significant errors, but in general it < seems reasonable to assume that the midpoint of the range is closer to the true figure than either of the extremes. It was assumed in addition, that the sectoral distribution of gross fixed .investment at market prices could be used to represent the distribution at factor cost. Eastern European Countries For Czechoslovakia, Poland, Hungary, and Bulgaria, the estimates of economic growth are mainly from the work of the Research Project on National Income in East Central Europe at Columbia University under the direction of Thad Alton. This project has published monographs on the structure of the Czechoslovak, Polish, and Hungarian economies and a large number.o~TATINTL Occasional Papers of the project have either beer_ published $5 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 The principal publications of the project, as well as some STATINTL of~the main supplementary sources used in this paper are listed at the end. STATINTL For East Germany, extensive use was made of the work of Wolfgang Stolper (The Structure of the East German Economy, Cambridge, 1960) and of estimates by Edwin Snell. For Rumania, use was made mainly of official Rumanian series and of __________ . calculated _an _ _ ,`index of industrial productior~/by the Alton project. 1. Sectoral Weights and Share of Investment in GNP The percentage distribution of GNP at factor cost provided the weights for the principal sectors of origin with which sectoral indexes could be combined to calculate indexes for total GNP. For Czechoslovakia, Poland and Bulgaria in 1956 and for Hungary in 1955, the distribution of GNP at factor cost was obtained from the Alton studies with one adjustment. To estimate the contribution of each sector to the GnTP at factor cost, the :~ Alton studies first determine the labor cost attributable to each sector. ~ejrthen impute the cost of non-labor factors by redistributing to each sector the part of total GNP in established prices which is not accounted for by labor costs in proportion to the sectoral distribution of fixed and working capital. This procedure implies a constant rate of return to all types of capital. Although this assumption has some theoretical merit, rates of return actually vary considerably in market economies among the usually sectors, the return,/being much lower on housing than on other assets. .Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 A~~ro~~d For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 r is reason, and to avoid making housing services an unreasonably large share of GNP, the Alton estimates were adjusted to give housing a rate of return one-half as high as that of the economy as a whole. In the absence of any detailed national accounts on Rumania, it was assumed that the sectoral distribution of Rumanian GNP at factor cost in 1956 was the same as that of Bulgaria. This analogy was suggested by the roughly comparable level of industrialization of these countries in 1956 (as ~e.flected in similar per capita GNP's) . For East Germany, estimates by Snell of the distribution of GNP in 1936 German Marks were used. Stolper's work shows that it makes little difference in the sectoral distribution whether 1936 Reichsinarks_ or 1950 Deutschmarks are used. Unfortunately, detailed postwar estimates in East . German marks are not available, but what information does exist on the East German national accounts and price structure appears to indicate that prewar German prices do not greatly distort the picture. The estimates of gross fixed investment as a share of GNP at factor cost in Czechoslovakia, Poland, Hungary, and Bulgaria are from Alton, except for an adjustment for housing corresponding to that on the sector of origin side of the accounts. For East Germany they are from Snell. As for Western Europe, it was assumed that the sectoral distribution of gross fixed investment at market prices could be used to represent the aistribution at factor cost. 87 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 2. Sectoral and End Use Indexes The Sectoral indexes and those for personal consumption and gross fixed investment cover the postwar years from 1950 through 1864 and a prewar year (1939 for Bulgaria, 1937 for Czechoslovakia and Poland, 1936 for East Germany, and 1938 for Rumania}. Prewar estimates are intended to represent production in the postwar territory, except in Poland, where they represent the prewar territory. All indexes for Czechoslovakia and Poland, (through 1962) and for Hungary (through 1960), the Sectoral indexes for Bulgaria (through 1960, and the industrial production index for Rumania (through 1964}, are from Alton. The methods of calculating these indexes are approximations of those used in Western countries. Industrial production indexes were obtained mainly by aggregating commodity series in physical units by means of weights made up of wage bills or other substitutes for value added, supplemented by prices. Construction indexes were obtained from data on inputs of materials into construction. Agricultural indexes were calculated from estimates of agricultural output (final product) of all major agricultural commodities, from which estimates of industrial inputs were deducted. Indexes for services are a composite of such indicators as ton-kilometers carried in various modes of transport, 'retail trade turnover in constant prices, the growth of the housing stock, and employment in various types of private and government services. Personal consumption indexes reflect the weighting of series on consumption of goods and Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 services, mainly in terms of physical units, by retail prices and value of purchases. ~e indexes for fixed investment combine estimates of construction expenditures (usually the same as those for GNP originating in construction) with estimates of apparent consumption of machinery and equipment. The Alton estimates were extended for the years after 1862 mainly by adjusting official Eastern European series. Official series for national income originating in industry,. construction, agriculture, and other "productive" sectors were used for Czechoslovakia, Poland and Hungary. Comparisons show that the differences between most of these official series and the calculated series have tended to decline over the years and in some cases (for example, industrial production in Poland that the differences had disappeared. ,Consequently, the use of these official series probably does not give bad results, especially for only a few years. Two adjustments had to be made, however. First, some (rather arbitrary) allowance was made for the growth on "non-productive" services, which are not included in official Eastern European national income statistics. Second, the sectors were reweighted in line with the estimates for earlier years.' For both of these reasons, the calculated growth of GNP in these years differs considerably from the official growth of national income. For Rumania in the entire period; official indexes were used for value added in agriculture. For Bulgaria, official series for gross fixed investment, including investment by collective forms, were used. $9 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 The indexes for industrial production and agricultural production, in East Germany are from Stolper through 1957, and are simplified updatings of Stolper's series for later years. For personal consumption, Snell provided estimates through 1955 and a new quantity index, obtained mainly by weighting East German series on the consumption of individual commodities with West German retail price weights was used after 1955? The series on gross fixed investment were obtained from official East German data on investment in machinery and inconstruction and on investment in industry and agriculture in current prices, and from various estimates of price changes for machinery and construction. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Appendix C Foreign grade Statistics The foreign trade analysis required mutually consistent series on: (1) the value of imports and exports in current dollars; (2) the value of imports and exports in constant (1963) dollars; (3) the average unit value of imports and exports in relation to the 1963 price level. For Western European countries these series are available from the United Nationts Yearbook of International Trade Statistics, except the most recent years, which were covered by OECD statistics. For Eastern European countries, the series in current prices are from the UN source mentioned above and the statistical yearbooks of the various countries. Poland and Czechoslovakia for the postwar years and Bulgaria for both postwar years and 1939 also provide quantum indexes of imports and exports in their statistical yearbooks. A quantum index for Czechoslovakia, relating 1937 to 19-8, was obtained from Statisticky Zpravodaj No. 7-8, 19-9, p.251. This index was linked to the postwar index, which begins in 19+8. For Poland quantum indexes relating prewar to 1950 were taken from Josef Krynicki, Problemy handlu zagranicznega polski (Warsaw, 1958). This index was linked to the .official postwar quantum index in 1950. Unit value indexes for Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia and Poland were derived from the series in current dollars and the quantum series. It was assumed that average unit values for imports and exports in Rumania and Hungary changed in tn.e same way as the weighted average for Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, and Poland. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 For East Germany, the postwar export series beginning in 1957 and the import series for the entire postwar period are from official East German statistical yearbooks. Official East German export data exclude reparations. Reparations were added by means of estimates by Snell which are based mainly on the publications of the West German Social Democratic Party (in particular, SPD Information Service, Die reparationen in der Sovietzone von 1945-1952, Denkschriften no. 51). Estimates of East and West German trade, including inter-regional trade, in 1936 are from UN~ECE, Econornic Bulletin for Europe, 1949, no. 3, p.26. 7~is source gives a breakdown of trade in the Soviet zone of occupation, West Germany and Berlin in 1936, with each other and with the outside wo~l:d. To obtain a correspondance with the postwar division of Germany, the trade of Berlin was further subdivided between East and West Berlin. The estimates of prewar East and West German trade in 1936 prices were linked to estimates of postwar trade in the same prices. Western E~zropean trade statistics are given f.o.b. for exports, c.i.f. for imports. Eastern European trade statistics were given this same way before World War II, but since 1950 imports have been given f.o.b., except in Hungary. To achieve greater comparability with Western statistics and prewar Eastern statistics, the postwar import series for the Eastern European countries; except Hungary, were increased by 11.1 percent (on the assumption that the f.o.b. value of imports was g0 percent of the c.i.f. value). Other possible causes of differences -- for example, in the treatment of re-exports and in the method of recording trade (by country of origin or destination or by country of payment) -- were not adjusted for. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RD~9T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Principal Sources of Statistical Data I. Publications of the Research Project on National Income in East-Central Europe at Columbia University Alton Project Monographs: Czechoslovak National Income and Product in 1j47-48 and 1955-56 (Columbia University Press, 19 2 ? Hungarian National Income and Product in 1955 (Columbia University Press, lg 3 Polish National Income and Product in 1954 1955 and 1956 (Columbia University Press, 19 5 Occasional Papers (Multilithed): Published to date: 1. Growth of Czechoslovak Trade, Banking, and Insurance, 1937-1862. 2. Trends in Czechoslovak Housing, Government, and Other Services, 1936-1862. 3. Czechoslovak Index of Investment, 1937-1862: Machinery and Equipment. 4. Czechoslovak Index of Construction, 1937-1862. 5? Indexes of Polish Industrial Production, 1937-1960. 6. Output of Czechoslovak Forestry, Fishing, and Hunting, Trapping and Game at Constant 1848 Prices, 1936 and 1946-1962. 7. Czechoslovak Agricultural Output, Expenses, Gross and Net Product and Productivity, 1934-1938 and 1946-1862. 8. Hungary, Index of Transportation and Communication Services, 1938-1862. 9? Output and Value Added in Czechoslovak Transportation and Communications, 1937 and 1846-1962.. Awaiting Reproduction: Personal Consumption in Poland, 1938 and 1846-1962. Czechoslovak Industrial Production Index, 1937-1962. Personal Consumption in Hungary, 1938 and 1947-1962., Czechoslovak Gross National Product by Sectors of Origin and by End Uses, 1937 and 1948-1862. Index of Hungarian Domestic and Foreign Trade, 1938 and 1947-1962. Trends in Hungarian Construction, 1938 and 1847-1962. National Income and Product of Bulgaria in 1956. Trends in the Service Sectors of the Hungarian Economy, 1938-1962. Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3 II. Other Statistical Sources on Eastern Europe Official Statistical Yearbooks (various years): Bulgaria: Statisticheski Godishnik ?? Czechoslovakia: Statisticka Rocenka ? East Germany: Statistisches Jahrbuch Der Deutschen Demokratischen Republik Hungary: Statisztikai Evkonyv Poland: Rocznik Statyst3-czny Rumania: Anuarul Statistic Other Sources: Wolfgang Stolper, The Structure of the East German Economy (Harvard University Press, lg 0 Greger Lazarcik, The Performance of Socialist Agriculture: A Case Stud of Production and Productivit in Czechoslovakia 193 -3 and lg - 1 ]L.W. International Financial Research Inc., lg 3 . Vaclav Holesovsky, Personal Consumption in Czechoslovakia, 1937, 1g~+8-1860 (University Microfilms Publications - PHD Dissertation, Columbia University . U.S. Bureau of Census, Foreign Demographic Analysis Division, Estimates and Projections of the Population and Labor Force of the European Communist Countries, 1950, 1955- 5 Mimeographed, March, 19 5 III. United Nations and OECD Sources OECD, Statistics of National Accounts, 1950-1861 OECD, General Statistics, January, 1g65 OECD, Manpower Statistics, 1950-1g62 OECD, Main Economic Indicators (Various Issues) United Nations, Yearbook of International Trade Statistics, 1860 and 1863 Approved For Release 2001/04/12: CIA-RDP79T01049A003200110001-3